Menu
Tax Notes logo

Updated CRS Corporate Tax Reform Report Discusses New Proposals

OCT. 8, 2021

RL34229

DATED OCT. 8, 2021
DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
Citations: RL34229

Corporate Tax Reform: Issues for Congress

Updated October 8, 2021

Congressional Research Service
https://crsreports.congress.gov
RL34229

Jane G. Gravelle
Senior Specialist in Economic Policy

SUMMARY

In 2017, the corporate tax rate was cut from 35% to 21%, major changes were made in the international tax system, and changes were made in other corporate provisions, including allowing expensing (an immediate deduction) for equipment investment. Recently, proposals have been made to increase revenue from corporate taxes, including an increased tax rate, and revise the international tax provisions to raise revenue. These revenues may be needed to fund additional spending or reduce the deficit.

Some level of corporate tax is needed to prevent corporations from becoming a tax shelter for high-income taxpayers. The lower corporate taxes adopted in 2017 made the corporate form of organization more attractive to individuals. At the same time, higher corporate taxes have traditionally led to concerns about economic distortions arising from the corporate tax and newer concerns arising from the increasingly global nature of the economy. In addition, leading up to the 2017 tax cut, some claimed that lowering the corporate tax rate would raise revenue because of the behavioral responses, an effect that is linked to an open economy. Although the corporate tax has generally been viewed as contributing to a more progressive tax system because the burden falls on capital income and thus on higher-income individuals, claims were also made that the burden falls not on owners of capital, but on labor income — an effect also linked to an open economy.

The analysis in this report suggests that many of the concerns expressed about the corporate tax are not supported by empirical evidence. Claims that behavioral responses could cause revenues to rise if rates were cut do not hold up on either a theoretical or an empirical basis. Studies that purport to show a revenue-maximizing corporate tax rate of 30% (a rate lower than the prior statutory tax rate) contain econometric errors that lead to biased and inconsistent results; when those problems are corrected the results disappear. Cross-country studies to provide direct evidence showing that the burden of the corporate tax actually falls on labor yield unreasonable results and prove to suffer from econometric flaws that also lead to a disappearance of the results when corrected, in those cases where data were obtained and the results replicated. Many studies that have been cited are not relevant to the United States because they reflect wage bargaining approaches and unions have virtually disappeared from the private sector in the United States. Overall, the evidence suggests that the tax is largely borne by capital. Similarly, claims that high U.S. tax rates created problems for the United States in a global economy suffer from a misrepresentation of the U.S. tax rate compared with other countries, because the comparisons focus on statutory rate. Tax rates are less important when capital is imperfectly mobile, as it appears to be, and because these concerns did not address the fundamental issues of efficiency in international taxation.

Although these new arguments appear to rely on questionable methods, the traditional concerns about the corporate tax appear valid. Although an argument may be made that the tax is still needed as a backstop to individual tax collections, it does result in some economic distortions. These economic distortions, however, have declined substantially over time as corporate rates and shares of output have fallen, even before the 2017 tax cut. Lower corporate taxes also create a way of sheltering individual income given the low tax rates on dividends and capital gains.

In addition to higher tax rates, a number of revisions could be made to increase corporate tax revenue, including

  • eliminating preferences in the corporate tax that mismeasure income or lead to economic inefficiencies,

  • revising the tax treatment of foreign source income, and

  • changing shareholder level taxes.


Contents

Introduction

The Corporate Tax as a Revenue Source

Magnitude and Historical Pattern

The Role of the Corporate Tax in Backstopping the Individual Tax

Behavioral Responses and Revenue-Maximizing Tax Rate

Theoretical Issues

Revenue Feedback from a General Equilibrium Model to Illustrate Likelihood of a Laffer Curve Near Pre-2017 Rates

Reduced Form Empirical Analysis

Brill and Hassett Study

Clausing Study

Cross-Country Investment Estimates: The Djankov Study

Theoretical Issues

Empirical Analysis

Distributional Effects

The Harberger and Randolph Studies

The Hassett and Mathur Study

Other Empirical Wage Studies

Other Cross-Country Studies of General Burden

Cross-State Regressions

Rent Sharing Studies

What Should Be Concluded About Incidence?

Economic Efficiency Issues

Allocation of Capital Within the Domestic Economy

Savings Effects

International Capital Flows

Potential Revisions in the Corporate Tax

Corporate Tax Expenditures

CBO Budget Options

Biden Administration's Proposals

Congressional Proposals

The House Ways and Means' Build Back Better Act

Draft Proposal by Senators Wyden, Brown, and Warner

Other Options Proposed in Prior Congresses

Evaluating Tax Revisions

Increasing Individual Level Taxes; Shifting Between Corporate and Individual Form

Conclusion

Tables

Table 1. Effective Tax Rates for Alternative Forms of Organization Under Alternative Rate Structures, Individual at 39.6% (43.4%) Rate

Table 2. Revenue-Maximizing Tax Rates and Share of Variance Explained in the Clausing Study

Table 3. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is Corporate Revenues as a Percentage of GDP (Brill and Hassett Model)

Table 4. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is Corporate Revenues as a Percentage of GDP (Clausing Model)

Table 5. Coefficient Estimates: Key Independent Variable is Constructed Effective Tax Rate (Djankov, Ganser, McLiesh, Ramalho, and Shleifer Model)

Table 6. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is the Logarithm of the Five-Year Average of Wage Rates

Table 7. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is Annual Logarithm of Real PPP-Adjusted Wage Rates

Table 8. Differential Tax Rates Across Asset Types

Table 9. Effective Tax Rates by Sector and Type of Finance

Table 10. Ten-Largest Corporate Tax Expenditures, 2020

Table 11. Revenue Gain from CBO Budget Options, FY2021-FY2030

Table 12. Estimated Revenue Gain from the Biden Administration's Corporate Tax Proposals, FY2022-FY2031

Table 13. Revenue Gain from International Provisions in S. 991 (Sanders), FY2022-FY2031

Table 14. Revenue Gain from Corporate-Related Provisions in the House Build Back Better Act, FY2022-FY2031

Table 15. Relevant Corporate and Business Tax Provisions in the Wyden-Gregg Bill, S. 3018, Introduced in 2010

Table B-1. Standard Deviation of Corporate Tax Rate Variables in the Three Data Sets

Appendixes

Appendix A. Revenue-Maximizing Tax Rates in an Open Economy

Appendix B. Data and Estimation Methods

Appendix C. Modeling Problems of the Desai, Foley, and Hines Study

Appendix D. Bargaining Models and Rent-Sharing of Corporate Taxes

Contacts

Author Information


Introduction

As Congress considers tax revisions, an important and challenging component is the tax treatment of the corporation. Following an extensive debate, corporate tax rates were reduced and other major changes were made to the corporate tax system in 2017 (P.L. 115-97), especially to the international tax treatment. Proposals have now been made to increase the corporate tax rate, revise international tax rules, and make other changes to raise revenue.

The traditional arguments surrounding the corporate tax, which largely focus on distortions introduced by the tax, were discussed in a January 2017 Treasury study.1 This study also discussed choice of organizational form and international issues. The debate leading up to the 2017 revision included arguments that cutting the corporate tax rate would stimulate economic growth, and even raise revenue, or on claims that the tax is a burden not on capital but on labor. Leading up to the revision, Steven Mnuchin, then-Secretary of the Treasury, advanced the argument that the corporate tax is paid by workers, citing a study by Azémar and Hubbard as evidence.2 A news report indicated three additional articles referenced by the Treasury press office in support of the burden falling on wages (although the Treasury Office of Tax Analysis currently assigns most of the burden to capital income): studies by Randolph, Hassett and Mathur, and Lui and Altshuler.3

Opinion pieces at that time referenced a variety of other studies that found large effects of corporate taxes on economic growth or the burden of the tax falls on wages, 4 whereas others expressed disagreement.5

These issues remain important ones to consider with a new debate on the corporate tax rate and on revisions in international tax rules.

The current debate raises issues similar to one that began more than 10 years ago and might be viewed as the beginning of the 2017 reduction in the corporate rate,6 as well as the more recent proposals for partially reversing the 2017 rate cut and revising the international system. Before turning to the basic issues surrounding the corporate tax, it is useful to trace this history of the discussion of issues and proposals for corporate reform.

In November 2005, President George W. Bush's Advisory Panel on Tax Reform reported on a variety of proposals for major reform of the tax system, including those for corporate and business income taxes.7 Hearings were held on these proposals in 2006, but no further action occurred.

On July 16, 2007, The Wall Street Journal published an opinion article by Treasury Secretary Henry M. Paulson addressing concerns that the U.S. corporate tax rate is high relative to other countries and announcing a conference to be held July 26 that would examine the U.S. business tax system and its effects on the economy.8 The Department of the Treasury also released a background paper that addressed several issues associated with the corporate tax and identified some base broadening provisions.9 An opinion piece by R. Glenn Hubbard, President Bush's first chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors, referred to the conference as well as to a study by Hassett and Mathur finding that the tax fell on labor and a study by Devereux considering the revenue-maximizing tax rate.10 Hubbard concluded by suggesting that cutting the corporate tax rate would reduce a tax that is largely, or even fully, borne by labor and that behavioral responses would offset much of the static revenue cost.

During the conference, discussions included whether business representatives would trade tax preferences for lower rates, whether reform should take the form of lower rates or write-offs of investments, and methods of avoiding the corporate tax by income shifting in a global economy. Some participants complained that the corporate tax is outdated, too complex, distorts decisions, and undermines the ability of firms to complete in a global economy. Echoing some issues raised in Hubbard's article, Kevin Hassett indicated that the corporate tax was not an effective way to raise revenues and suggested that lowering the rate would raise revenues.11

At the time of the Treasury conference, Chairman Charles B. Rangel of the House Ways and Means Committee released a statement inviting the Bush Administration to discuss such issues as tax reform, especially the alternative minimum tax (AMT), addressing tax havens, and increasing equity and fairness in the tax structure.12 Chairman Rangel introduced a bill, H.R. 3970, on October 25, 2007, with a revenue-neutral subsection that included some of the base broadeners included in the 2007 Treasury paper noted above. The rate reduction, from 35% to 30.5%, was not as large as the 27% discussed in the 2007 Treasury study. Base broadeners in H.R. 3970 were criticized by some business groups.13

The corporate tax debate and the issues of burden and effects on growth continued to be in the news. In May 2008, N. Gregory Mankiw published an article suggesting that most of the burden of the tax falls on labor, citing research suggesting the corporate tax is borne by labor and that revenue losses may be fully or largely offset by behavioral responses.14

In the 111th Congress, S. 3018, introduced by Senators Ron Wyden and Judd Gregg, also provided for a lower corporate tax rate in exchange for a somewhat broader corporate tax base. A similar bill, S. 727, was introduced by Senators Wyden and Coats in the 112th Congress. The Fiscal Commission proposed a corporate reform similar to the Wyden-Gregg bill. In addition to the Wyden-Gregg and Wyden-Coats proposals and the Fiscal Commission proposals, there were general proposals by Republican leaders in the House (Majority Leader Eric Cantor, Ways and Means Chairman Dave Camp, and Budget Committee Chairman Paul Ryan) for corporate tax reform with rate reductions.

In 2014, Chairman Camp introduced H.R. 1, a comprehensive proposal that reformed both individual and corporate income taxes and was revenue neutral during the 10-year budget horizon, as well as distributionally neutral. It cut the corporate tax rate to 25%. President Barack Obama also supported revenue-neutral corporate tax reform, although some groups proposed raising additional revenue from corporations.15 During 2016, Senator Hatch, chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, indicated an interest in corporate tax integration (where only one level of tax would be imposed on corporate income).16 Subsequently, Speaker Paul Ryan and Ways and Means Committee Chairman Kevin Brady proposed a major revision in the tax treatment of business income in their “Better Way” blueprint. It partially transformed the current income tax into, effectively, a domestic consumption tax. The border adjustments that make this proposal a domestic consumption tax appeared no longer on the table and a new plan was under discussion in cooperation with the House, Senate, and Administration.17

The 2017 tax revision, which included temporary individual tax revisions and permanent corporate and business tax changes that reduced revenue, lowered the corporate tax rate from 35% to 21%. It made major changes to international tax rules by moving from a regime where income of foreign subsidiaries was taxed only when profits were repatriated as dividends were paid to the U.S. parent to one where dividends were exempt but foreign profits taxed after an exemption for a deemed return on tangible assets and after a deduction to lower the rate. This provision was designed to tax global intangible low-taxed income (GILTI) at a lower rate and is referred to as a global minimum tax. (In prior and current law, credits were allowed against U.S. tax for foreign taxes paid, although these credits are allowed on an overall basis that allows foreign taxes in high-tax countries in excess of the U.S. rate to shield income in low-tax countries from U.S. tax). GILTI allowed a deduction for a deemed return on tangible assets of 10%. The GILTI regime was accompanied with a deduction for foreign derived intangible income (FDII) that allowed a deduction for U.S. firms based on their share of foreign sales, with a similar deduction for a deemed return on tangible assets. It was designed to equalize the treatment of return on intangible investments whether held in the United States or abroad. International provisions also included the base-erosion and anti-abuse tax (BEAT), which imposed an alternative tax at a lower rate on a base that included certain payments by U.S. multinationals to foreign related parties (such as interest and royalties) and that denied certain credits. Numerous other revisions were made in the corporate tax base, most notably allowing the expensing (an immediate deduction) of the cost of equipment, although this treatment is scheduled to be phased out over four years beginning in 2023.18 The revision also provided for a five-year period to deduct the cost of research expenses after 2021, which are currently deducted immediately.

This report provides an overview of corporate tax issues and discusses potential reforms in the context of these issues, with particular attention to some of the research concerning large behavioral responses and their implications for revenue and distribution. The first section reviews the size and history of the corporate income tax, and it discusses an important issue that has been given little attention by those who proposed deep cuts in the corporate tax: its role in preventing the use of the corporate form as a tax shelter by wealthy business owners. The second section discusses the potential effect of behavioral responses on corporate tax revenues. The third section examines the role of the corporate tax in contributing to a progressive tax system and discusses claims that the burden falls on workers. The fourth section reviews arguments relating to efficiency and revenue yield and traditional criticisms of the corporate tax as one that causes important behavioral distortions. One aspect of this discussion is the question of how the tax might be viewed differently in a more global economy. The final section examines options for reform.

The Corporate Tax as a Revenue Source

The corporate tax is the third-largest source of federal revenue, but its importance as a revenue source has diminished considerably over time.

Magnitude and Historical Pattern

Despite concerns expressed about the size of the corporate tax rate, current corporate taxes are low by historical standards, whether measured as a share of output or based on the effective tax rate on income.19 In 1953, the corporate tax accounted for 5.6% of GDP and 30% of federal tax revenues. In recent years, prior to the 2017 revision, the tax has fluctuated at around 2% of GDP and 10% of revenues, reaching a low of 1.2% of GDP in 2003, and standing at 2.7% in 2006 before falling as a share due to the recession and certain measures to stimulate the economy. By 2014, the tax was 1.9% of GDP falling to 1.5% in 2017; after the 2017 revisions, the tax was 1.0% of GDP. Projections indicate that the tax, after falling to 0.7% of GDP in FY2021 due to the recession, will rise and remain at around 1.3% of GDP. Today, it is the third-largest federal revenue source, lagging behind the individual income tax, which is 7.7% of GDP in 2020, rising to 9.4% in FY2031, and the payroll tax, which was about 6% of GDP. It is more significant, however, than excise taxes, which are 0.4% of GDP, and estate and gift taxes at less than 0.1%. In FY2020, the corporate tax is estimated at 6.2% of revenues, rising to 6.85% by FY2031.

Much of the historical decline arises from legislated reductions in the corporate effective tax rate on the return to new investment, which has fallen from 63% of corporate profits in 1953 to about 3% today. These changes include a reduction in the top statutory rate from 52% to 21%, more liberal depreciation rules, and the growth of tax favored intangibles investments.20 The total tax burden on corporate source income has declined even more due to lower rates on dividends and capital gains at the shareholder level and the increased fraction of stocks held in tax exempt form.

Although a large fraction of the decline in corporate tax revenues is associated with these changes in rates and depreciation, other causes may be more liberal rules that allow firms to obtain benefits of corporate status (such as limited liability) while still being taxed as unincorporated businesses and tax evasion, particularly through international tax shelters. The 2007 Treasury study documented the significant rise in the share of total business net income received by unincorporated businesses from 1980 to 2004, from 21% of total net income to 50%. Whereas the share of proprietorships (which have no limited liability) had declined slightly, from 17% to 14%, the share of Subchapter S firms (firms that are incorporated but are allowed to elect taxation as an unincorporated business) rose from 1% to 15%. These changes followed a dramatic increase in the number of shareholders allowed for the election (the limit of 10 was raised to 35 in 1982, to 75 in 1996, and to 100 in 2004). Partnerships (including limited liability corporations and limited liability partnerships) increased from 3% to 21%, with most of the increase occurring after 1990. This growth reflects in part the growth of limited liability corporations established under state law (the first state adopted such a provision in 1982), which qualify as an unincorporated businesses for corporate tax purposes. Whereas Subchapter S firms are constrained by the shareholder limit, partnerships are not.21

The latest data (for 2015) indicate that unincorporated businesses accounted for 50% of the total of flow through and corporate business net income, with S Corporations accounting for 15%, partnerships for 25%, and proprietorships for 11%.22

The Role of the Corporate Tax in Backstopping the Individual Tax

Measuring corporate tax revenue falls short of describing the full role of the corporate tax in contributing to federal revenues because the corporate tax protects the collection of individual income taxes. As long as taxes on individual income are imposed, a significant corporate income tax is likely to be necessary to forestall the use of the corporation as a tax shelter. Without a corporate tax, high-income individuals could channel funds into corporations, and, with a large part of earnings retained, obtain lower tax rates than if they operated in partnership or proprietorship form or in a way that allowed them to be taxed as such. As suggested by the growth in unincorporated business forms above, wealthy business owners may be quick to take advantage of tax rate differentials, which currently tend to favor unincorporated businesses. In 1986, individual tax rates were lowered dramatically (the top rate fell from 70% to 28%, although it was eventually increased to 39.6%), but the combined corporate tax rate (on the firm and on distributions) has been high relative to the individual tax rate. The 2007 Treasury study indicated that 61% of the income of unincorporated businesses was associated with taxpayers in the top income tax bracket.

Although the top tax rate on corporations prior to the 2017 revisions (35%) was close to the top individual rate (39.6%), the corporate tax was graduated. Consequently, for high-income taxpayers, there was an advantage to shifting part of one's income into a corporation because corporate tax rates are graduated (15% on the first $50,000 and 25% on the next $25,000) and are lower than the top marginal tax. This opportunity, however, was restricted by (1) limiting to one the number of corporations income can be shifted to; (2) the amount on which rates are graduated; and (3) disallowing graduated rates for personal service corporations. In recognition of the potential use of the corporation as a shelter, tax law has in the past contained a tax on accumulated earnings. As long as dividends were taxed as ordinary income and the accumulated earnings tax was strict enough, it was difficult to use the corporate form to shelter a great deal of income.

This tax shelter constraint on lowering the corporate rate may have become more binding because of the lower rates on dividends enacted as part of the Administration's corporate relief package in the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (P.L. 108-27), although rates were increased in 2010 and 2013.23 The 2017 revision also changed the relative benefits of operating in corporate versus noncorporate form by lowering the corporate rate to 21% and the individual rate to 37%, which would tend to make the corporate organizational form more attractive to high-income individuals. It also, however, eliminated the graduated rates that allowed a restricted opportunity for use of the corporate form as a shelter and also, allowed a deduction for 20% of pass-through income for unincorporated businesses, although the deductions was phased out for certain taxpayers.24 The individual provisions are scheduled to expire after 2025, but the corporate rate cut is permanent. Businesses at high income levels are subject to an additional 3.8% tax on their income either due to the Medicare A hospital insurance tax or the net investment income tax applied to passive investment income, passive business income, dividends, and capital gains. Active income from a Subchapter S firm that is not wages is not subject to the tax.

Table 1 calculates the effective tax rate for operating through a corporation for high-income taxpayers versus an unincorporated business for several cases: (1) pre-2017 law (a 39.6% top individual tax rate with and without the 3.8% and a 35% corporate rate), (2) current law (a 37% top rate with and without the pass-through deduction or the 3.8% additional tax and a 21% corporate tax rate), and (3) law after the lapse of the individual tax rates (a 39.6% tax rate with and without the 3.8% tax and a 21% corporate tax rate). In all cases, corporate dividends are subject to a top rate of 23.8% (a tax rate of 20% plus the 3.8% investment tax).25 Table 1 also presents proposals discussed by the Biden Administration to raise the corporate tax rate to 28%, the top individual rate to 39.6%, and to tax capital gains at ordinary income.

Under prior law, the effective corporate tax rate ranged from 35% to 50.5% depending on the share of dividends, whereas the top effective individual rate was typically 43.4%. Unless a corporation distributed very little of its income, corporate tax rates were usually higher than individual rates, favoring the unincorporated form even more for individuals in lower tax rates. After the 2017 revision, the corporate form could sometimes become beneficial even without the graduated rates. For taxpayers not eligible for the pass-through deduction and especially those subject to the net investment income tax, the corporate form becomes preferable, whereas for firms eligible for the pass-through deduction the noncorporate form would often become preferable. However, if the lower tax rate and pass-through deduction expire, as scheduled in 2025, corporate organization becomes more attractive. (Individuals with lower individual rates could still find noncorporate organization preferable.) Although the 2017 changes weakened the preference for noncorporate form and therefore could be argued to weaken the use of the corporation as a backstop for the individual tax, it also eliminated the graduated corporate rates. All of these changes, along with the uncertainty about the future, create a complex picture of organizational preference.

The proposals advanced by the Biden Administration to raise the corporate rate to 28% and restore the 39.6% top individual rate, as well as taxing dividends and capital gains at ordinary rates, would make the corporate form unattractive as a tax shelter as long as the pass-through deduction expires and the corporation distributes dividends.

Table 1. Effective Tax Rates for Alternative Forms of Organization Under Alternative Rate Structures, Individual at 39.6% (43.4%) Rate

Corporate Business

100% of Income Distributed

50% of Income Distributed

No Income Distributed

Dividends Taxed at 20% Rate

Corporate Tax Rate of 35%

50.5

42.7

35.0

Corporate Tax Rate of 21%

39.8

30.4

21.0

Corporate Tax Rate of 28%

45.1

36.6

28.0

Dividends Taxed at Ordinary Rates

Corporate Tax Rate of 35%

63.2

49.1

35.0

Corporate Tax Rate of 21%

55.3

38.1

21.0

Corporate Rate of 28%

59.2

43.6

28.0

Unincorporated Business

39.6% No Net Investment Income Tax

39.6

39.6

39.6

39.6% With Net Investment Income Tax

43.4

43.4

43.4

39.6% No Net Investment Income Tax with Pass-Through Deduction

31.7

31.7

31.7

39.6% With Net Investment Income Tax with Pass-Through Deduction

35.5

35,5

35,5

37% No Net Investment Income Tax

37.0

37.0

37.0

37% With Net Investment Income Tax

40.8

40.8

40.8

37% No Net Investment Income Tax with Pass-Through Deduction

29.6

29.6

29.6

37% With Net Investment Income Tax with Pass-Through Deduction

33.4

33.4

33.4

Source: Congressional Research Service (CRS) analysis.

Behavioral Responses and Revenue-Maximizing Tax Rate

Although it has long been recognized that there are behavioral responses to the corporate tax (even aside from the tax sheltering issues indicated above), and that these responses have important implications for the efficiency of the economy and the burden of the tax, the issue of a revenue-maximizing tax rate, popularly associated with the “Laffer” curve, has rarely entered into the discussion. A Laffer curve graphs revenue against the tax rate, and is based on the notion that revenue is zero at a zero tax rate and zero at a 100% tax rate (at least with respect to some taxes).26 In a Laffer curve, the revenue first rises with the tax rate and then falls, and at the point it reverses direction is the revenue-maximizing tax rate.

The notion that a corporate tax cut could pay for itself continued to enter the debate in 2017,27 as it did 15 years ago during that corporate debate, where it was proposed or alluded to in several articles in the popular press during the debate. One is the article by Glenn Hubbard, cited above. In National Review, Kevin Hassett discussed the Laffer curve and presented a chart that he indicated is an illustration that appears to show a negative relationship between corporate revenues as a share of GDP and the tax rate.28 Only 13 countries are shown on this graph, however, and the negative relationship is clearly strongly affected by an outlier, Ireland, which is a well-known tax haven; most economists would not find this illustration persuasive proof.29 The Hubbard and Hassett articles do, however, cite some more sophisticated research. Hassett referred to a paper by Kimberly Clausing,30 and Hubbard referred to a paper by Michael Devereux.31 In addition, Alex Brill and Kevin Hassett also prepared a statistical analysis examining the change in the relationship over time.32 A cross-country study was also prepared by Jack Mintz.33 Clausing, who is referred to in the Hassett article, is quoted as claiming that the United States is likely to the right of the revenue-maximizing point on the Laffer curve, but this statement, presumably from an earlier draft, is not found in her published article. That article finds a revenue-maximizing tax rate of 33%, in her simple specification, but as she added variables and accounted for other features the revenue-maximizing tax rate seemed to rise, as indicated in Table 2. Large countries and countries that are less open, such as the United States, have a revenue-maximizing tax rate of 57% — much larger than the combined federal and state rate for U.S. firms of 39%.

Table 2. Revenue-Maximizing Tax Rates and Share of Variance Explained in the Clausing Study

Specification

Tax Rate

R-Squared

(1) Basic

33%

0.13

(2) Additional Variables

39

0.43

(3) Additional Variables

42

0.46

(4) Additional Variables

41

0.23

(5) Additional Variables

37

0.21

(6) Openness

43

0.27

(7) Size

45

0.23

(8) Openness and size

57

0.28

Source: Kimberly Clausing (2007).

Note: The R-Squared is a statistical term that measures the share of the variance in the dependent variable explained by the independent variables.

Michael Devereux's paper indicates that, while he finds a revenue-maximizing rate of 33% under the same specification as Clausing, he finds only weak evidence of a relationship between tax rates and corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP. Many of his specifications do not yield statistically significant effects. Brill and Hassett find a rate of around 30%, which has been falling over time. Mintz finds a rate of 28%, but his data span only a few years (2001-2005).34

The remainder of this section first discusses theoretical expectations of this relationship and then examines these empirical studies. Both the theoretical and empirical assessments suggest that the results of these analyses are questionable.

Theoretical Issues

The issue of a Laffer curve has not been a part of the historic debate on corporate taxes because the notion of a revenue-maximizing tax rate other than at very high tax rates is inconsistent with most of the models of the corporate tax. Traditionally, the main behavioral response associated with the corporate tax was the substitution of noncorporate capital for corporate capital within an economy where the amount of capital was fixed. Imposing a corporate tax (in excess of the noncorporate tax) caused capital to earn a lower return in the corporate sector and to flow out of that sector and into the noncorporate sector, thereby lowering the return in the noncorporate sector and raising the return, before taxes, in the corporate sector. The higher pretax return on capital also caused prices to go up in the corporate sector and fall in the noncorporate sector, causing a shift toward noncorporate sector total production. The corporate profits tax base, therefore, had two opposing forces: the amount of capital was falling but the profit rate was rising. The taxable base could, therefore, either increase as tax rates increased, or it could decrease. The direction depended on the substitutability of capital and labor in the corporate sector. The central tendency of most models (with unitary elasticities) suggested, however, that the tax base was relatively invariant to tax rates, and revenues would always rise with the tax rate. Consequently, under any reasonable set of assumptions there would either be no revenue-maximizing tax rate or an extremely high one.35

If behavioral responses caused the total capital in the U.S. economy to contract, the outcome could be different. One such model, the open economy model, appears to be a motivation for the belief in a relatively low revenue-maximizing tax rate. Brill and Hassett discuss elasticity estimates of foreign capital flows to after tax returns in the range of 1.5 to 3 (they also cite a recent study with an elasticity of 3.3) in their paper that finds a revenue-maximizing tax rate of around 30%. They conclude that “[t]hese high elasticities are consistent with the view that reductions in corporate rates could lure a significant enough amount of economic activity to a locality to create a Laffer curve in the corporate tax space.”36

As shown in the Appendix A, however, this tax rate even with infinite elasticities cannot be achieved. In the most extreme case, where (1) the country is too small to affect worldwide prices and rates of return; (2) capital is perfectly mobile; and (3) products in international trade are perfectly substitutable; the revenue-maximizing tax rate would be the ratio of the labor share of income to the factor substitution elasticity. Assuming fairly common values for a model without depreciation of 75% for labor's share of income and a factor substitution elasticity of 1, the tax rate would be 75% — far above the rates of around 30% reported by Brill and Hassett. This rate could rise as these conditions are relaxed. If the United States is assumed to have 30% of world resources, the rate rises to 81%; if imperfect substitutability between investments across countries and between foreign and domestic products is allowed, it would rise further. It would also rise if the tax system included elements of a residence-based system that increases the tax rate on foreign investment by imposing a tax on foreign branch income and on dividends paid by foreign subsidiaries to the U.S. parent, reducing the tax advantage of outbound investment.

Although it is possible to have a revenue-maximizing tax rate that does not asymptotically approach 100%, it is probably not possible to find a rate that maximizes revenues as a percentage of GDP because GDP falls as well as tax revenues. In this case, the same circumstances apply as in the reallocation of capital in the closed economy: with unitary elasticities, the corporate share of income is constant relative to GDP, and with other elasticities, it can rise or fall.

A related circumstance where capital can contract would be in a model where savings responds so powerfully that the savings supply is infinitely elastic, that is, when a tax is imposed, the capital stock must contract so much, and the pretax rate of return rises so much that the after-tax return comes back to its original value. This extreme savings response model yields the same revenue-maximizing tax rate as the extreme open economy, 75%, and probably no revenue-maximizing tax rate for revenues as a percentage of GDP. Moreover, the slowness with which the capital stock adjusts (most models allow 150 years for full adjustments) means that the revenue would be affected by tax rates in the past.

The result of this discussion makes it clear that revenue-maximizing tax rates cannot arise from physical reallocations or contractions of capital. Nor are they likely to arise from a substitution between debt and equity, since the debt share has changed very little despite significant changes in the relative tax burden, and estimates of elasticities that do exist are small.37

A remaining source of a different outcome is profit shifting. This effect could involve firms maintaining the same activity and shifting the form of operation to unincorporated businesses. Profit shifting could be a possibility (although the point of revenue maximization would be much too low because much of the tax has not disappeared, but rather has shifted). But, at least in the United States, this shift is probably less the result of high corporate tax rates and more the result of increasingly loose restrictions on operating with limited liability outside the corporate form, actions that have not been taken by other countries.38 The other profit shifting issue is the shifting of profits (rather than activity) to foreign countries. Such effects are possible, but it would seem unlikely that tax avoidance could be of this magnitude, given the amount of profits shifted and the behavioral response. Although a small low-income country, as is characteristic of most tax havens, might have little enough domestic capital that it could afford the loss from lowering the rate to attract more capital, such an outcome is much less likely for the United States. Recent estimates of elasticities also suggest that cutting the corporate tax rate would lower revenue much more than enough to offset the tax on profits shifted back into the United States.39

In addition, profit shifting can be prevented or limited by revisions in international tax rules. Concerns about this issue led to the imposition of tax on GILTI in 2017, which imposes a minimum tax on foreign source intangible income. Early evidence indicated, however, that the share of related company profits reported in tax havens did not change despite the lower tax rate or the global minimum tax.40 One explanation is that a smaller tax rate may not result in much change in the location of profits from intangible assets, which can be shifted easily as much as the law allows to zero-tax rate countries. That is, even if the U.S. rate is lowered from 35% to 21%, both rates are still higher than a zero rate and there is little incentive to shift profits back to the United States. GILTI lowered the rate to 10.5% although the cross crediting of foreign taxes means zero rates can persist in some locations. One solution is to tax income from tax havens at the full U.S. rate by raising GILTI rates and imposing a per country limit on the foreign tax credit so income in tax havens cannot be shielded from U.S. tax by credits from foreign taxes in high-tax countries.

Revenue Feedback from a General Equilibrium Model to Illustrate Likelihood of a Laffer Curve Near Pre-2017 Rates

A Laffer curve with a revenue-maximizing tax rate implies that there is a point where the tax base contracts so much that no revenue is gained from a tax increase, and, conversely that cutting tax rates could raise revenue. Revenue offsets that arise from behavioral responses are often referred to as a revenue feedback. For a tax cut, revenue feedback would be the revenue gain from an expanded base as a percentage of the original revenue loss (for a tax increase, it would be the loss from a contraction in the base as a percentage of the original gain). The revenue-maximizing tax rate is the point where induced changes in the tax rate provide 100% revenue feedback.

An approach that is empirically based but which is not the result of a direct estimate involves using a general equilibrium model, which is based on empirical estimates of underlying relationships (such as capital mobility). A CRS report used such a model and concluded that cutting the corporate tax from 35% to 25% in isolation would result in a revenue offset of 5% due to taxes on increased output in the United States.41 This effect was not due to the increase in corporate taxes on the additional output, which was negligible, but to an increase in both labor and capital income taxes on increased output. Thus the revenue-maximizing tax rate cannot be near the current 35% tax rate.

As noted earlier, some have argued that the revenue feedback for the corporate tax arises not from real changes in investment but from artificial profit shifting, where multinationals use a variety of techniques to declare income in low tax countries. Analysis and evidence, however, does not support this effect.

Finally, all of these feedback effects would eventually be swamped for a stand-alone tax cut by the increase in the debt, which would crowd out capital and reduce output, leading to an additional loss of revenues of 23% by the 10th year. This loss of revenues on reduced output is in addition to the direct effect on the budget deficit due to an increase in interest costs of 25% of the revenue loss over the first 10 years.

Reduced Form Empirical Analysis

As noted above, several recent studies have examined the relationship between corporate tax rates and corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP. The data used for two of these studies were obtained to replicate and extend the analyses. Both studies and the analysis estimate the effect of the top corporate tax rate (and its square) on corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP. Panel data for 29 OECD countries is used for the analysis.

Brill and Hassett Study

In their study, Brill and Hassett use panel data for the OECD countries from 1981 to 2003.42 They use regression analysis (OLS) to estimate the effects. Brill and Hassett find that the corporate tax rate has at first a positive effect on corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP and then a decreasing effect — the effect looks like an inverted U, the shape of the classic Laffer curve. All of their coefficient estimates are statistically significant. However, they do not account for problems often encountered with the use of panel data, and their coefficient estimates would appear to be biased and inconsistent.43

The estimation results from the re-analysis of the Brill and Hassett study are reported in Table 3. The regression includes a tax rate and a tax rate squared to allow for a curve. Panel A of the table displays the results for central government corporate tax data (in the case of the U.S., this is federal government tax data). The coefficient estimates for the full time period (1980 to 2003) and the four subperiods defined by Brill and Hassett are reported. In all cases, the coefficient estimates are fairly small and none are statistically significant at conventional confidence levels. Panel B of the table displays the results for total government (that is, governments at all levels) corporate tax data. Again, the coefficient estimates are fairly small and none are statistically significant. Once appropriate estimation methods are used to correct problems arising with panel data, there appears to be no statistically significant relation between corporate tax rates and corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP.

Table 3. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is Corporate Revenues as a Percentage of GDP (Brill and Hassett Model)

 

1980-1986

1987-1992

1993-1997

1998-2003

1980-2003

A. Central government corporate tax revenues; federal corporate tax rate

Tax rate

-0.037

(0.090)

-0.110

(0.081)

0.048

(0.087)

0.049

(0.117)

-0.040

(0.040)

Tax rate squared

0.087

(0.109)

0.122

(0.100)

-0.082

(0.129)

-0.060

(0.178)

0.052

(0.053)

F (joint)

5.15

1.21

0.33

0.21

0.51

Prob > F

0.008

0.303

0.719

0.809

0.603

B. Total government corporate tax revenues; total corporate tax rate

Tax rate

0.204

(0.195)

-0.042

(0.077)

0.069

(0.076)

0.037

(0.094)

-0.016

(0.038)

Tax rate squared

-0.193

(0.214)

0.044

(0.091)

-0.106

(0.109)

-0.008

(0.123)

0.028

(0.047)

F (joint)

2.25

0.21

0.51

0.74

0.44

Prob > F

0.112

0.811

0.602

0.481

0.612

Source: CRS analysis.

Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. Fixed effects linear model with AR(1) disturbance. Other variables include time dummy variables.

Clausing Study

Clausing uses panel data for the OECD countries from 1979 to 2002 to study the effect of corporate tax rates on corporate tax revenue as a percentage of GDP.44 She includes more explanatory variables than did Brill and Hassett, but her overall research findings and conclusions are essentially the same as theirs — there is a Laffer curve relationship between corporate tax rates and corporate tax revenue as a percentage of GDP. However, her estimation methods would lead to biased and inconsistent coefficient estimates.45

The estimation results for five different specifications are reported in Table 4. The five specifications differ by what explanatory variables are included in the analysis. In all five specifications, the coefficient estimates of the corporate tax rate (and its square) are smaller than those estimated by Clausing and have the opposite signs. Most of the coefficient estimates are not statistically significant at conventional confidence levels, but two are statistically significant at the 10% level only. (In these cases where the coefficients are significant on the tax squared term they still do not produce the Laffer curve shape but rather suggest rising revenue with a rising tax rate). Overall, these results suggest that the corporate tax rate has little effect on corporate tax revenues as a percentage of GDP. Consequently, there is little evidence to support the existence of a corporate tax Laffer curve.

Table 4. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is Corporate Revenues as a Percentage of GDP (Clausing Model)

 

Specification

 

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Tax rate

-0.055

(0.035)

-0.073

(0.111)

-0.075

(0.046)

-0.048

(0.036)

-0.067

(0.047)

Tax rate squared

0.078*

(0.047)

0.118

(0.147)

0.102*

(0.061)

0.069

(0.048)

0.093

(0.061)

Profit rate

 

X

 

 

 

Corporate share

 

X

 

 

 

Unemployment rate

 

 

X

 

X

Per capita GDP growth rate

 

 

X

 

X

Per capita GDP

 

 

X

 

X

Openness

 

 

 

X

X

F (joint)

1.39

0.75

1.45

1.04

1.21

Prob > F

0.251

0.473

0.236

0.354

0.298

Source: CRS analysis.

Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. Fixed effects linear model with AR(1) disturbance. Other variables include the indicated variables and time dummy variables. *significant at 10% level.

Even if an empirical study found a statistically significant relationship that indicated a revenue-maximizing tax rate, such results could not be considered reliable if they do not control for base changes. If the rate is lowered but the base is broadened, the data could show rising tax revenues that would be due to the base changes. In a recent paper, Slemrod and Kawano provide estimates controlling for the direction of changes in the base (although not the magnitude, a much more daunting task) and find these controls raise the estimated revenue-maximizing tax rate.46 Thus, until studies can adequately control for the magnitude of changes in the base, they cannot be the basis for estimating a revenue-maximizing tax rate.

Cross-Country Investment Estimates: The Djankov Study

Cross-country empirical studies, as noted above, have recently been employed to address the Laffer curve issue and, as will be discussed subsequently, the incidence of the corporate tax on wages. In addition to these direct estimates, there are numerous empirical studies that examine underlying relationships, such as the effect of the user cost of capital (which incorporates the tax rate along with other variables) on investment. Most of these studies have found modest effects on domestic investment and have employed times series estimates within the United States.47

One recent study on investment, Djankov et al.,48 is similar to the other studies in that it employs a cross-country data base and an independent variable reflecting the tax rate to directly estimate the effect of the corporate tax rate on investment, entrepreneurship and other variables. The study found no effect on investment for statutory tax rates, but very large effects for constructed first year and five year cash flow tax rates. This study, unlike the others discussed in this paper, is a single cross section, so there is no way to introduce fixed country effects.

Theoretical Issues

Several difficulties arise in the Djankov analysis. First, the cash flow tax rate variable they construct is a hypothetical one (for a hypothetical firm), which is not representative of the capital stock or the firm size in a country (or in all countries). The denominator is income measured before labor income taxes paid by the firm (such as social security taxes in the United States) and economic depreciation. The first is very problematic because the capital income tax rate increases as the labor income tax rate falls, which is a relationship that seems to have no obvious economic justification. It also measures taxes on a cash flow basis for the first year (or the first five years in an alternative scenario), rather than over the life of the investment.

An examination of scatter-plots of their data suggest that the results are highly affected by outliers, particularly Bolivia (which has a very high tax rate and a very low investment rate) and Mongolia, a low tax country where investment has been flowing in recently due to mining.

The tax rate for Bolivia is about twice the typical tax rate and is inconsistent with the corporate rate in Bolivia. According to the authors, the tax rate reflects an alternative transactions tax. However, a transactions tax is not a tax on corporate income but falls on all income in the economy. Assuming that about a quarter of income is capital incomes, the tax should be reduced by 75%.

As with the Laffer-curve estimates, the results of this study, at least for the United States, are not plausible. According to their estimates, a 10 percentage point drop in corporate tax increased investment by 2.2 percentage points. According to an open economy model developed by Gravelle and Smetters,49 however, U.S. capital would increase a maximum of 0.7 percentage points with the elimination of corporate tax; with more reasonable elasticities, it would increase by 0.3 percentage points. (This study was directed at the question of tax incidence and will be discussed in more detail in the section below which addresses distributional issues and the burden on labor). Moreover, these effects may understate the investment effects because they do not take into account debt. Thus, their results suggest an investment increase that is at least 11 times too large and that could be 25 or more times too large.

Empirical Analysis

Although the issue of fixed effects would cause this study to remain problematic in any case, this section explores the effects of the tax rate changes and of specifications that include multiple control variables.

The Djankov et al. sample consists of 2004 tax and economic data for 85 countries. They examine the effect of the corporate tax rate on (1) aggregate investment, (2) foreign direct investment, and (3) two measures of entrepreneurial activity. The main results of their study and the authors' reanalysis are reported in Table 5. The first row of the table displays the coefficient estimate of the effective corporate tax rate variable taken from the Djankov et al. study. Their basic specification includes only the tax rate as an independent variable. The second row of the table reports the range of estimates when a single additional independent variable is added — the authors add 10 variables, one at a time. In all but one instance, the estimates are statistically significant at the 1% or 5% confidence level, and at the 10% level in the remaining case.

Their data was reanalyzed after correcting an error in their tax rate for Bolivia, and cumulatively adding selected independent variables that Djankov et al. included in their analysis; the new analysis also included a region-of-the-world variable for each country. The first row of the bottom panel in Table 5 presents the coefficient estimates for the basic model with only a single independent variable: the effective corporate tax rate. For each dependent variable, the coefficient estimate of the tax rate variable is smaller than Djankov et al. 's estimate, which illustrates the importance of Bolivia to their results. Furthermore, the estimated effect of the tax rate on aggregate investment is not statistically significant. The final row of Table 5 reports the coefficient estimate of the tax rate when the full set of independent variables is included in the analysis. The estimated effect of the tax rate on aggregate investment is much smaller than Djankov et al.'s estimate and not statistically significant. The estimated effect of the corporate tax rate on foreign direct investment and entrepreneurial activity is somewhat smaller than the effects estimated by Djankov et al., but the estimates are statistically significant.

Table 5. Coefficient Estimates: Key Independent Variable is Constructed Effective Tax Rate (Djankov, Ganser, McLiesh, Ramalho, and Shleifer Model)

 

Dependent Variable

 

Investment

Foreign Direct Investment

Business Density per 100 People

Average Business Entry Rate

Original Basic Estimate

-0.218a

(0.074)

-0.226a

(0.045)

-0.194a

(0.063)

-0.138b

(0.057)

Range of Estimate

-0.165 to -0.236

-0.189 to -0.233

-0.090 to -0.196

-0.110 to -0.141

Coefficient Estimates of Tax Rate Variable with Corrected Data

Basic Estimate

-0.108

(0.073)

-0.194a

(0.044)

-0.150b

(0.060)

-0.116b

(0.055)

PLUS

Region Indicators

-0.046

(0.071)

-0.191a

(0.045)

-0.115b

(0.058)

-0.126b

(0.056)

PLUS

Per Capital GDP

-0.031

(0.070)

-0.190a

(0.045)

-0.148a

(0.050)

-0.146a

(0.055)

PLUS

Number of Tax Payments

Employment Rigidity Index

-0.025

(0.076)

-0.179a

(0.048)

-0.154a

(0.055)

-0.097c

(0.057)

Procedures to Start a Business

Source: CRS analysis.

Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis.

a. Significant at 1% level.

b. Significant at 5% level.

c. Significant at 10% level.

Distributional Effects

A second issue that was a focus of the Hubbard article was the distributional effects of the corporate income tax. (Note that these distributional effects are driven by some of the same effects that drive the issue of a revenue maximizing tax rate or economic growth: the inflow of capital from abroad.) The distributional issue also had been referenced by then-Treasury Secretary Mnuchin, who cited a study by Azémar and Hubbard as evidence that most of the corporate tax is paid by workers.50 If the corporate tax falls on owners of the corporation, or on capital in general, it contributes to a progressive tax system, since higher income individuals have more income from capital than from labor. Based on tax data, for taxpayers with incomes up to $100,000, over 90% of income is labor income, whereas those with incomes over $1 million, less than a third is labor income.51 The traditional analysis of the corporate income tax indicates that the burden generally spread to all capital, but does not fall on labor income. Most government and private agencies that routinely do distributional analysis allocate the corporate tax largely to capital income.52

Hubbard referred to three studies in his article: a working paper by economist Arnold Harberger,53 a working paper by William Randolph of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO),54 and a recent empirical cross-country study using data similar to the studies discussed above, by Hassett and Mathur.55 At about the same time or shortly thereafter three other empirical studies that use cross-country data were released in 2006-2008, by Felix,56 by Desai, Foley and Hines,57 and by Arulampalam, Devereux, and Maffini.58 Mankiw referred to the Randolph and Arulampalam, Devereux, and Maffini studies, although as will be shown subsequently the Arulampalam et al. study is examining an entirely different phenomenon which is unlikely to be very relevant to the United States corporate tax, as is the case with the Azémar and Hubbard article referred to by then-Treasury Secretary Mnuchin.

These studies reflect differing fundamental approaches to studying corporate tax incidence. One approach uses a general equilibrium model that estimates incidence based on empirical estimates of various behavioral responses and other aspects (such as size). The burden that falls on labor versus capital depends on international capital flows and how well they can be used in different countries (which in turn depend on the technology of production and the preferences of consumers). The second approach is to directly estimate wages as a function of tax rates and other variables from a set of data (this approach is called a reduced form estimate). These direct estimates, in turn, fall into two types: (1) some studies are considering the effects of international capital flows and (2) others are examining the share of the tax on excess profits (or rents) that is born by labor by reducing the share of rents that is captured by labor in wage bargaining. Of the studies mentioned in the previous paragraph, two (Harberger and Randolph) are of the general equilibrium type; three (Hassett and Mathur, Felix, and Desai, Foley, and Hines) are reduced form empirical estimates that reflect capital flows; and two (Arulampalam, Devereux, and Maffini and Azémar and Hubbard) are estimating rent sharing through wage bargaining.

A news report indicated three articles referenced by the Treasury press office in support of the burden falling on wages (although the Treasury Office of Tax Analysis currently assigns most of the burden to capital income): two studies already mentioned, Randolph, and Hassett and Mathur, and a study by Lui and Altshuler.59 The last study does not clarify what behavioral response it is measuring, but because it is based on considering wage effects by industry it would be capturing wage bargaining effects.

The Harberger and Randolph Studies

The first two studies explicitly focus on the effects of an open economy. It is a standard finding that for a small open single-good economy with perfect capital mobility and perfect product substitution, the burden of any source based capital income tax falls on labor (whereas for residence based taxes, that is taxes that apply to domestic owners of capital regardless of where they are domiciled, the burden would fall on capital). The corporate tax had some aspects of a source based tax and some of a residence based tax.

Both the Harberger and the Randolph studies are based on this simple model of perfect substitution, altered to account for the United States as a large county (which lowers the elasticities) and to account for multiple sectors. Randolph's study does not so much predict the burden of the tax as explore incidence in certain types of models; he acknowledges that less capital mobility causes the burden to shift from labor to capital. Harberger's model has four sectors, corporate and noncorporate tradable sectors and corporate and noncorporate nontradable sectors. He assumes that the corporate tradable sector is more capital intensive than the average industry, which leads to a burden of greater than 100% of the tax falling on capital. Despite the vision of the manufacturing sector as highly capital intensive, it actually is not: housing services, which are 100% capital, account for over a third of the capital stock in the country, and many other industries, such as utilities and agriculture are also more capital intensive than manufacturing. Using the same assumptions about mobility, but with a less capital intensive manufacturing sector, Randolph finds 70% of the corporate tax burden falls on labor.

To permit other than perfect substitutability, a much more complex computable general equilibrium model would be required, which neither Harberger nor Randolph has provided. Such a model has been developed by Gravelle and Smetters60 who find, with reasonable elasticities, that capital still bears most of the burden, about 80%. A recent CBO working paper by Jennifer Gravelle provides an extensive review of the existing general equilibrium models and the factors that drive the results.61 She finds that five factors tend to move the burden toward falling on capital: a smaller willingness of consumers to substitute between foreign and domestic products, a higher substitutability of labor and capital in the production process, a smaller willingness of investors to substitute investments in different countries, a less capital intensive corporate tradable sector, and a larger country. Her review of the evidence on these factors suggests that, based on these models, the majority of the tax (about 60%) is born by capital, with results differing from the Gravelle and Smetters findings due to a lower substitution elasticity between capital and labor in production.62 She subsequently considers, however, other factors that could increase the burden on capital (and even benefit labor), including the use of debt (discussed below).

Although the general equilibrium models can be very complex, they still abstract from some important features of the corporate tax. There are several other factors that would further push the corporate tax burden toward capital. First, if some share of profits is rent, it would be expected to fall on capital in the United States, because only a small share of the private sector (less than 7%) is unionized.63 Second, the current corporate tax actually subsidizes debt finance at the firm level, and if debt is much more substitutable than equity, total capital would be less likely to be exported: indeed, raising the corporate tax rate could cause capital to flow in. A study by Grubert and Mutti found that in a general equilibrium model that included debt, such a capital inflow occurred when capital income taxes were raised, an outcome that would lead to labor benefitting from the corporate tax.64 The burden would also be likely to fall on capital if elements of a residence tax were reimposed in the United States (there are some minor current elements because branch income abroad is subject to tax). The current international tax regime under GILTI allows a deduction for 10% of tangible income, largely exempting the income from tangible investments of foreign subsidiaries from tax. Eliminating that exemption and raising the GILTI rate to the full U.S. rate would lead to a worldwide, or residence-based tax (such a change could be accompanied by an elimination of the deduction for FDII, whose exemption for tangible investment discourages the investment tangible capital in the United States because an increase decreases the deduction).

Finally, note that as long as countries tend to choose tax rates similar to each other, which appears to be the case, the world becomes like the original closed economy, a model stressed by Harberger, with the burden falling on capital. According to the 2007 Treasury study, the U.S. combined state and federal corporate statutory rate was 39%, the G-7 average was 36%, and the OECD average was 31%. In 2013, the rates had declined slightly, with rates of 29% in the OECD and 30% for the largest 15 countries (both excluding the United States). Effective tax rates, which should govern the movement of capital, are even closer together, and in some cases are lower for the United States than for other countries. More recent updates of tax rates indicated that U.S. rates were similar to the rest of the world.65 Jennifer Gravelle used OECD tax rates to estimate the share of the U.S. tax falling on labor using a global approach and finds that over 90% falls on capital.66

An argument is often made that the burden of any capital income tax tends to fall on labor because it reduces savings, an effect that would also occur in a closed economy. While one version of the model predicts that the entire burden of a capital income tax eventually falls on labor, this version requires some extreme assumptions about human behavior such as perfect information, an infinite planning horizon, perfect liquidity, and asexual reproduction. Models allowing for finite lives (such as the life-cycle models) find results that vary, but if the revenue loss is made up by higher taxes on labor, there is little or no effect. Some economists believe that these models are inappropriate, as they assume too much information and skill on the part of individuals; they suggest that individuals use rules of thumb, such as fixed savings rates or targets, instead. These rules of thumb suggest that a cut in capital income taxes either has no effect on saving or reduces savings. These economists also point out that most empirical evidence does not point to an increase in savings; historically, savings rates do not appear to respond to reduced tax rates.67

The Hassett and Mathur Study

Whereas the general equilibrium models do not provide much support for the corporate tax burden falling on labor, Hubbard also referred to an empirical study by Hassett and Mathur that uses the corporate tax rate to explain differences in manufacturing wages.68 They find a statistically significant result that indicates a 1% increase in the corporate tax causes manufacturing wages to fall by 0.8% to 1%. These results are impossible, however, to reconcile with the magnitudes in the economy. Through competition, wage changes in manufacturing should be reflected in wages throughout the economy, implying that a 1% rise in corporate revenues would cause a 0.8% to 1% fall in wage income. However, corporate taxes are only about 2.5% of GDP at best, whereas labor income is about two thirds. These results imply that a dollar increase in the corporate tax would decrease wages by $22 to $26, an effect that no model could ever come close to predicting.69

The lack of theoretical reasonableness of the results may be explained by statistical issues. The Hassett and Mathur study used data from 72 developed and developing countries for the 1981 to 2003 period.70 For their analysis, their dependent variable is the logarithm of the five-year average of the average manufacturing wage. They justify their use of the five-year average wage by (1) noting that due to capital adjustment costs, the economic effects of corporate tax rate changes show up over longer time periods, and (2) arguing that this may control for possible measurement error induced by the business cycle.71 The wage rates for all countries were converted to U.S. dollars using annual exchange rates. Hassett and Mathur include the price level of consumption as an explanatory variable to capture cost of living differences across countries. The main explanatory variable of interest is the logarithm of the top corporate tax rate. Hassett and Mathur also use the average effective and marginal effective corporate tax rates (in logarithms) as explanatory variables in some specifications.

The Hassett and Mathur basic estimation exercise was replicated: the results are reported in the first row of Table 6.72 The coefficient estimate reported in the first column (-0.759) suggests that a 10% increase in the top corporate tax rate will lead to a 7.6% decrease in the average manufacturing wage rate. This estimate is statistically significant at the 5% level.73 The results are not as strong (the estimates are closer to zero) when using alternative measures of the corporate tax rate (see the next two columns of Table 6).

The exchange rate between two currencies reflects the relative supply and demand for those two currencies, and is affected by financial markets and government policies. Exchange rates may not be good indicators of the relative buying power of wage rates in two countries. Purchasing Power Parities (PPPs), however, are specifically designed to equalize the internal purchasing power of the currencies. Workers in Australia, for example, are concerned with what their wages will purchase in Australia, and not how many dollars their wages will buy. Using PPPs is a more appropriate way to convert national currencies to a common currency (U.S. dollars).

The second row of Table 6 reports the coefficient estimates when the wage rates are converted to U.S. dollars using the consumption PPPs. Consumption PPPs are more appropriate for converting wages than using general PPPs (over GDP) because they omit national expenditures for government and investment goods. Again, nominal wages are the dependent variable. The coefficient estimates are closer to zero than the estimates reported in the first row, but the coefficient estimate reported in the first column (-0.728) is statistically significant at the 5% level. The estimates for the alternative measures of the corporate tax rate are not statistically significant at the conventional confidence levels.

Table 6. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is the Logarithm of the Five-Year Average of Wage Rates

How Wage Variable Converted to U.S. Dollars 

 Corporate Tax Rate Variable

Top Tax Rate

Effective Average

Effective Marginal

Exchange Rate

-0.759a

(0.297)

-0.630b

(0.334)

-0.384b

(0.226)

Purchasing Power Parity Exchange Rate (PPP)

-0.728a

(0.303)

-0.528

(0.340)

-0.334

(0.230)

PPP — Constant Dollars

-0.488b

(0.298)

-0.294

(0.318)

-0.218

(0.215)

Observations with Five-Year Averages Based on Five Years of Data 

Exchange Rate

0.089

(0.353)

-0.229

(0.363)

-0.184

(0.240)

Purchasing Power Parity Exchange Rate (PPP)

-0.037

(0.354)

-0.187

(0.373)

-0.156

(0.246)

PPP — Constant Dollars

-0.064

(0.350)

-0.230

(0.351)

-0.180

(0.231)

Source: CRS analysis.

Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. Fixed effects linear model. Other variables include time dummies, log personal tax rate, log real value-added, log consumer price variable (except for real PPP).

a. Significant at 5% level.

b. Significant at 10% level.

The most appropriate measure of wages is the inflation-adjusted consumption PPP-adjusted wage rate. Wages in each country were converted to U.S. dollars using the consumption PPP and then converted to constant (inflation-adjusted) dollars using the CPI-U before calculating the five-year average. The final row of Table 6 displays the coefficient estimates for the model using this measure as the dependent variable. The estimates are closer to zero than in the other two cases. The coefficient estimate in the first column (-0.488) is statistically significant at the 10% level but not at the 5% level. The other two estimates in columns two and three are not statistically significant at the conventional confidence levels. Although there is still some evidence of corporate tax rates having a negative influence on wage rates in manufacturing, the effect is smaller and less robust than reported in the Hassett and Mathur study.

Hassett and Mathur averaged wages over five-year periods. They justify using five-year averages by arguing that it helps to control for possible measurement error induced by the business cycle. But, because of missing values in the wage data, 66 observations have the average wage based on less than five years of data (60 observations use only two consecutive years of data for the calculation of the average, which would likely not affect any measurement error). The bottom panel of Table 6 reports the estimation results when these 66 observations are excluded from the analysis (leaving 153 observations). In all cases, the coefficient estimates for all measures of the corporate tax rate are not statistically significant.

Averaging the wage data over five years and using the beginning of period value for the explanatory variables, however, eliminates much of the variation in wages and tax rates, thus throwing away much of the information needed to estimate the economic effects. The statistical analysis is repeated using annual data and including various lagged values of the corporate tax rate as explanatory variables.74 The results are reported in Table 7. The first column of the table displays the coefficient estimates for the current value of the corporate tax rate (labeled t in the first column) and the values for the previous five years (t-1 to t-5), which allows for longer term effects of tax rates on wages. In each case, the coefficient estimates are negative but very close to zero; none are statistically significant at the conventional confidence levels. Furthermore, all the tax rate variables in column (1) are not jointly statistically significant. The next six columns report the results when the corporate tax rate values (current and lagged) are entered individually. In every case, the coefficient estimates are close to zero and are not statistically significant at conventional confidence levels. In using annual data, there is no evidence that changes in the top corporate tax rate affects wage rates in manufacturing.75

Table 7. Coefficient Estimates: Dependent Variable is Annual Logarithm of Real PPP-Adjusted Wage Rates

Tax Rate Lag

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

t

-0.031

(0.208)

 

 

 

 

 

0.010

(0.140)

t-1

-0.217

(0.188)

 

 

 

 

-0.219

(0.143)

 

t-2

-0.076

 

 

 

-0.074

 

 

 

(0.166)

 

 

 

(0.144)

 

 

t-3

-0.040

(0.159)

 

 

0.021

(0.145)

 

 

 

t-4

-0.113

(0.156)

 

-0.070

(0.146)

 

 

 

 

t-5

-0.154

(0.155)

-0.165

(0.147)

 

 

 

 

 

F (joint)

0.49

 

 

 

 

 

 

Prob>F

0.819

 

 

 

 

 

 

Source: CRS analysis.

Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. Fixed effects linear model with AR(1) disturbance. Other variables include time dummies, log personal tax rate, log real value-added. ***Significant at 1% level; **significant at 5% level; *significant at 10% level.

Hassett and Mathur subsequently produced a revision of their initial paper.76 One of several generic problems with cross-country wage studies is that a proper specification should take into account not only the country tax rate but the rates of other countries. (Other generic problems include the direction of causation, for example, that countries with lower or slowly growing wages may choose to rely on corporate taxes as a revenue source, so that the wage changes may drive the corporate rate.)77 Hassett and Mathur address the first issue, in a limited fashion, by adding tax characteristics of neighboring or economically similar countries. This addition, in some cases, reduced the coefficient on taxes and made it statistically significant at a lower level. The study also included some local price indices, but this change did not fully address the issue of comparing wages using purchasing power and did not address other issues raised about the original Hassett and Mathur study. Their results continued to produce implausible estimates. In the case where average tax rates of countries with similar income levels was added, the percentage change in wages for a 1% change in corporate taxes is 0.5%. This level implies a decrease of $13 in wages for each dollar fall in corporate taxes.78

Other Empirical Wage Studies

Several other studies have examined the incidence of the tax on labor income. They are discussed in three different categories: studies that rely on cross-country data as in the case of Hassett and Mathur, studies that rely on cross-state data, and studies that examine not the general incidence of the tax, but the share affecting wages through bargaining over excess profits. The Arulampalam, et al. study cited by Mankiw was the first of these latter types of studies.

Other Cross-Country Studies of General Burden

Four studies in addition to the Hassett and Mathur study have relied on cross-country data. Felix,79 in a study that controls for education, finds much smaller effects than Hassett and Mathur, but ones that are still too large to be predicted by a theoretical model (about $4 for each dollar of corporate tax revenue). This study has problems similar to those for Hassett and Mathur and, in addition, does not control for country fixed effects, therefore not controlling for unobserved country-specific factors. The sample is unusual as well, with 19 countries covered for varying years. Out of the total of 65 observations (countries and years), about a quarter of the sample is drawn from Italy and Mexico and seven of the 19 countries had only one or two years of data.

Another study, by Desai, Foley and Hines80 uses observations on foreign owned affiliates of U.S. firms across countries and in different time periods. This study uses data on multinational subsidiaries of U.S. firms to estimate the allocation of the tax burden between labor and capital using a seeming unrelated regression for capital income (which they measure by the interest rate) and labor income. In their model, labor and capital burdens are restricted to the total of taxes, and they impose a cross-equation restriction on the estimated burdens. They find the share of the burden on labor income to fall between about 45% and 75% of the total, a number that is not inconsistent with theoretical expectations.

This approach, however, has the fundamental theoretical problem that wages at an individual firm should not reflect tax burdens at an individual firm. In deriving a model that assumes it does, they assume that the price level of their goods is fixed and base their results only on their sample of firms (which is comprised solely of multinational corporate sector firms). This approach creates both econometric problems in their analysis and also means that their results cannot be construed as reflecting actual burdens in any of their economies, as discussed in more detail in Appendix C.

They also represented equity returns through the interest rate, under the assumptions that investors equate (net of risk) debt and equity returns. If these assets are generally substitutable, the increase in corporate tax should cause portfolios to shift toward debt and drive the interest rate up (while driving the equity return down). Moreover, the tax burdens on debt and equity differ at the individual level and those differences depend, among other things, on any special tax rates for dividends and capital gains, the deferral advantage of capital gains, and the inflation rate.

Aside from these theoretical problems, an important issue with their study is that it appears that their results are forced by the cross equation restriction. William Randolph, a discussant at a 2008 conference, found that if the restriction is eliminated there are no statistically significant results from their study.81 In an example he presented, the estimates of the wage effect was 48% of the burden, with a standard error of 18% in the original study; in a regression without the restriction the share was 19% with a standard error of 100%.82 Randolph considered a number of other specifications, including excluding the largest countries, but found no statistically significant results. He also suggested that only manufacturing subsidiaries be considered since other subsidiaries may be involved in tax sheltering operations. In the case where he considered only manufacturing subsidiaries, the sign reversed (indicating labor benefitted from the tax) but it was not statistically significant.

Across-country study by Clausing used a data set covering the OECD countries.83 Her study examined a number of different specifications, econometric approaches, and alternative data measurements. Two aspects that differed from the Hassett and Mathur study were comparing wages using purchasing power parity and excluding value-added variables, which Clausing suggests is capturing the effect of corporate taxes (whose burden on labor operates by reducing labor productivity). She expects this latter change would make results for the corporate tax variable larger. Overall, however, while trying many specifications and approaches, she characterizes the results as indicating no robust evidence that corporate tax burdens have large depressing effects of wages. She notes, however, that this outcome does not necessarily mean there is no incidence on labor, but that these effects cannot be detected with aggregate cross-country data, a point also made by Jennifer Gravelle in her review of empirical studies.84

The most recent study, by Ebrayet and Geys, estimates a model that allows for countries to compensate for high labor costs by reducing the corporate tax. Their estimates, using 24 OECD countries, indicate that a 1% increase in the corporate tax rate reduces the average wage by from $0.51 to $0.89, implying a $6 to $11 increase in wages for a dollar increase in the corporate tax, an implausible result.85

Cross-State Regressions

Three studies estimate tax incidence based on cross-state comparisons, as if each state were a separate country. Felix examines wages by residents of states depending, among other factors, on the state corporate tax rates.86 She finds a smaller effect than the Hassett and Mathur or her own cross-country study, although the results remain implausible, suggesting that a $1 dollar increase in taxes reduces wages by between $1.40 and $3.60.87 Other problems with her data set is that it is not a panel, so there is no individual specific control, and the data set also does not allow the identification of place of work, but rather place of residence.

Felix and Hines use a similar cross-state data set.88 Although the stated objective of this study is to examine rent sharing by considering union and nonunion differentials, the paper also contains direct estimates of the effects on tax rates on wages. The relationships, however, are positive, not negative. Although the authors conclude that higher corporate tax rates reduce union wage differentials (a point associated with bargaining over surplus discussed in the next section), this differential arises in their empirical estimates because union wages rise less with corporate taxes than do nonunion wages. Thus these results directly contradict the results in the previous Felix study.

Carroll also examines individual workers across the states using a different data set. He estimates the effects of the statutory rate (combined federal and state) and also an average state tax rate.89 The first is only marginally statistically significant (and he does not highlight that result), but the second is highly significant. However, the average tax rate is measured not as taxes divided by profits but as taxes divided by personal income. Since personal income is strongly correlated with wages, this measure of tax would likely produce a powerful negative relationship without any direct relationship with taxes. As with other studies, the incidence estimated in this study is very large relative to the expected shares (he calculates $2.50 for every dollar of tax).

Another problem with cross-state studies is that states often allocate profits based on formulas and these formulas change the dynamics of capital flows. For example, if a firm's taxes are based on the share of sales, changing the location of production would not be relevant to the state tax burden. One recent study, by Suarez Serrato and Zidar, explicitly addressed the apportionment issue by controlling for the share of the tax that was based on a sales factor (other factors are capital and labor) and thus should not affect location.90 The study found 30% to 35% of the tax borne by labor. The study also used a spatial approach to address geographic location. A study by McKenzie and Ferede of the Canadian provinces did not control for the effect of formula apportionment (Canadian provincial taxes are levied 50% by sales and 50% by wages). The results of this study, were, however, implausible, finding a range of $0.96 to $1.59, depending on the province.91

One issue with cross-state studies is whether, even were there no concerns with particular studies, the results could provide guidance to the effects of the federal tax. Capital is likely significantly more mobile across states and products across states are probably closer substitutes, both factors that make the incidence more likely to fall on labor. Labor, however, is also mobile but its relative increase in mobility is probably less than that of capital. The states are also more like small economies on average. As in the case of cross-country studies, the tax rates of other states should be included in the regression. In addition, state corporate tax rates are much lower than the federal tax rate and it would be even more difficult to use this small explanatory variable to explain wages.

Rent Sharing Studies

Several studies have appeared recently that discuss the potential burden of the corporate tax on wages via an entirely different mechanism, which has been misinterpreted in some ways. As noted earlier, Greg Mankiw92 cited a study by Arulampalam, Devereux, and Maffini (hereinafter, ADM) finding a labor share of the corporate tax burden of 96% as evidence that the corporate tax fell largely on labor. (The most recent version of their study reports 49%).93 More recently, former Treasury Secretary Steve Mnuchin cited a study of this type by Azémar and Hubbard (AH) as evidence that the burden falls largely on labor (they found 60%).94 ADM, AH and other studies of this nature do not estimate the general equilibrium effects of corporate taxes on economy wide wages through capital flows but rather the share of the tax on excess profits that falls on workers due to bargaining and rent sharing, as do the other studies reviewed in this section. Because of the method of estimation, the Liu and Altshuler paper referenced by the Treasury Press Office would also be classed with rent-sharing studies. These rent-sharing studies have relatively little relevance to the general issue of the corporate income tax for the United States (in part, because the shares of workers who belong to unions that bargain on wages is so small). However, their results have been invoked as evidence on the general tax burden and these types of studies began proliferating, and they were cited as evidence that the burden falls on capital. The ADM study has apparently inspired several other studies of this nature, which are discussed here. These studies use individual firm or sector observations, which, as noted earlier, are not appropriate for the general incidence of the corporate tax, but are appropriate for the study of rent-sharing.

Before proceeding to examine both the ADM study and other studies specifically, it is important to make some general points about these types of studies as measures of the share of the corporate tax borne by labor.

First, even if a reliable measure of labor's share could be found, the share cannot be interpreted as the share of total tax falling on wages because the analysis relates only to excess profits, which are in turn only a part, perhaps a small part, of total profits. The share of rents also suggests an upper boundary to the share of the tax which falls on labor that should be detected through these studies. A widely cited study by Gentry and Hubbard estimated that 60% of corporate profits represented earnings in excess of a risk-free return.95 Since some (perhaps most) of the excess return is a risk premiums and is part of the opportunity cost of capital (not excess profit), the excess profit share should be lower. Some evidence suggests that it is in the neighborhood of 10% to 20%.96 Every empirical study discussed in this section exceeds that level, with the smallest about 35% and the largest many multiples of 100%. Moreover, the burden relates only to those firms that both have some excess profits and engage in bargaining. Whereas bargaining may be common in some European countries, in the United States, where unions would be expected to do the bargaining, less than 7% of private wage and salary workers are covered by unions.97

Second, there is an existing literature that has attempted to estimate the share of labor in excess profits (without focusing on tax issues). Most studies have found that, even in those circumstances where bargaining is to be expected, labor tends to capture a relatively small share, typically less than10% and rarely more than 20% or 30%.98 This small share suggests the amount of labor income due to rent sharing is small, and that is consistent with estimates that the union wage premium is about 15% (with a range of 0 to 30%).99 Thus the share of the total wage bill that reflects rents of union workers is 1% (the share of union workers, 7%, times the wage premium of 15%).

Thirdly, and perhaps the most important point to make, in the standard bargaining model (such as that employed by ADM), a corporate tax rate that applies to excess profits would not be expected to affect wages through the bargaining process. If taxes are treated in a standard way as a rate applied to a firm's revenue minus cost, the tax term does not appear (see Appendix D). The workers and firm would split pretax profits, with each paying tax (corporate or individual) on their share. The economic intuition behind this is that while a higher tax rate reduces the surplus or size of the pie to be divided, it also makes the “price” of giving a dollar to labor lower because wages are deductible. Economists might think of these as offsetting income and substitution effects and in this model they offset exactly.100

The only tax effect left is the one that arises (potentially) from the general equilibrium effects on the economy that occur due to the imposition of the tax on normal profits, an effect that applies to firms without excess profits and unions as well and could only be uncovered through some analysis appropriate to economy-wide effects. Under reasonable assumptions the proportional effect on rents is similar to the proportional effect of wages. Because the taxes on the excess profits themselves do not directly drive payments to labor, considering the possibility of rents simply means that an even smaller share of the total corporate tax burden falls on labor than suggested by the general equilibrium models. (For example, if the model estimates 20% of the burden will fall on labor and 25% of profits is excess, then only 75% times 20%, or 15%, of the burden falls on labor.) Given these theoretical insights, one might question why empirical studies of rent-sharing are being pursued at all as a question of tax incidence, and why such significant effects have been found.

The ADM study used firm level data (for about 55,000 firms) from several European countries (primarily France, Italy, Spain and Germany) over a relatively short time frame of 1996-2003.101 It controlled for firm-specific effects. About a quarter of the observations are for only four years and about 45% only five years so that the panel, like that of Felix, shows changes over the short run. The same authors had an earlier version of their study with a smaller sample. Although the authors control for firm level fixed effects, they do not control for country-specific effects. The authors have subsequently revised their study reporting, for the preferred specification, that labor bears 64% of the tax in the short run and 49% in the long run.102

The ADM study properly derives a model where the tax on revenues minus wages disappears and claims not to consider the tax on normal profits. Instead the authors hypothesize an extra tax term that is not associated with profit that will affect wages directly. It is difficult to imagine exactly what type of tax provision would fall into this category. In any case, the share of the corporate tax arising from this type of provision seems likely to be vanishingly small.103

Whatever the authors theorize about, it is not what they include in their regression. The variable is total taxes paid per worker (although it is instrumented with tax rates and other variables). The study also excludes other important variables which cannot be observed such as the competitive wage (they use a minimum wage which is obviously far too low). The empirical implementation examines the change in wages as a function of the change in output and taxes (all taxes, not just lump sum taxes) which are closely linked as major elements of a contemporaneous identity and may explain their findings. Thus, it is possible that the statistically significant relationships obtained derive from some other linkage and do not represent a share of the tax burden.104 There are also some important reservations about the econometric methods. Panel data with short time periods (where persistence effects can be serious) and the need to control for firm specific effects face some significant econometric problems. The authors use a number of different specifications, with widely varying results, which suggest that the results are not robust.105 There are several other aspects of the econometrics that are not transparent.106

Overall, it is not clear what relationship or phenomenon the study is measuring. Interest ideally is in how an exogenous tax change affects wages. Yet for some of the countries that constitute a large share of the data, there were no changes in tax rates. In others, tax rate changes were virtually all declines, with most of those declines occurring during the growth period of the late 1990s, when productivity and output was rising. It is possible that the results are capturing that phenomenon.

Another study using European data directed at capturing the bargaining share was recently released by aus dem Moore, Kasten, and Schmidt.107 This study compared the changes in wages of German manufacturing compared with French manufacturing, spanning a time when the German taxes were reformed (including rate cuts) and the French tax was not. This analysis finds a very large effect: an increase in German wages of 6.4% due to the rate cuts. This finding seems large. According to the reported means of the data, the ratio of wages to taxes is 11.9; that is wages are about 12 times the amount of taxes. If wages rose by 6.4%, that amount is 76% of the total corporate tax. It appears that the reduction in German taxes was around 20%, which implies, in dollar terms, that wages rose $4 for each dollar reduction in tax, when it should have been a share of only a small part of the tax. It seems likely that the empirical estimates are capturing some other type of influence, and the authors indicate their study is preliminary and uncertain. The authors never discuss the theoretical finding that this type of tax rate change is the kind of change that would not be expected to show up as a part of rent sharing.

Another study, by Dwenger, Rattenhuber, and Steiner, also uses firm data to examine the German tax cut.108 As with the aus dem Moore et al. study, they do not address theoretical concerns and simply assume that labor will bear some of the burden of the tax via bargaining. Their estimates of this initial wage effect indicate labor bears 156% of the tax. They also assume that the higher or lower wages will lead to employment shifts (so that when wages rise, employment falls and thus the wage bill does not fall as much), which results in a total wage bill effect of 47% of the tax. This line of reasoning regarding employment is also inconsistent with theory, as the wage does not change from the direct bargaining effect. Rather it arises from the increase in the cost of capital via increased taxes, which, while decreasing the demand for capital (assuming there is a nontaxed noncorporate or foreign sector), has effects on employment in the corporate sector that are uncertain. In a general equilibrium model, employment is assumed to be fixed in the economy. In any case, these general equilibrium effects cannot be uncovered with firm specific data within a country because the effect should not relate to the specific taxes of the firm. As with the aus dem Moore et al. study, it is not clear what the authors are measuring when they regress wage rates on tax rates, although it could reflect differential wage growth across industries.

A study of subnational taxes in Germany by Bauer, Kasten, and Siemers found a significant effect of the corporate tax on wages.109 In some ways, this study was similar to the cross-state studies done in the United States in that the explanatory variable was the tax rate. But it also addressed rent sharing by examining the differences between low-skilled workers with less bargaining power. As is the case with some other studies, the results are implausible. They found that a 1% increase in tax rate decreased wages by between 0.28% and 0.46%. Although the incidence was not as large as the Hassett and Mathur results, using the same ratio of wages to taxes as the aus dem Moore, Kasten, and Schmidt study indicated a dollar of corporate tax reduced wages between $3.36 and $5.52 or by 336% to 550%.

Fuest, Peichl, and Sioegloch report an incidence of 47% in a wage bargaining model, using data from German municipalities and a series of tax changes in the local business tax. This 47% includes an externally estimated excess burden (efficiency cost); without it the incidence would be 36%.110

A study by aus dem Moore, comparing outcomes in France and the UK in a w age bargaining model follows the approach of ADM, and finds the share falling on wages 39% in France and 40% in the UK in the short run. In the long run, the results indicate a share of 66% in France and 73% in the UK.111

Azémar and Hubbard estimated the incidence in a wage bargaining model using data on 13 OECD countries.112 Using the values for 2004, their estimates indicate 60% of the burden falls on labor. Further estimates that include measures of union density indicate that this effect is highly driven by union density and would probably be negligible for the United States.113

Two studies have been based on data in the United States. As noted earlier, Felix and Hines actually found wages to rise with increases in state tax rates, but the union differential fell. They indicate that their findings show that workers in a unionized firm bear 54% of the tax burden. Several important points should be understood about their analysis. First, as they make clear, they are not trying to estimate the effect of direct taxes on rents, as this effect disappears from their model. They are rather examining the indirect effect that would arise due to the increase in the cost of capital and the subsequent general equilibrium effects that would arise. Although they have correctly measured a statewide tax rate as their tax variable (rather than a firm specific rate), the model they use to drive their theoretical expectations has a mistake (as shown in Appendix D) and the expectation from a properly derived model is likely a close to zero effect, and if not zero probably positive. Their estimate appears outside the range of reasonable theoretical prediction and probably in the wrong direction. In addition in calculating incidence they have applied the elasticity to the entire wage bill, not the share that is rent. If the rent share is about 15%, 8% of the tax, not 54%, falls on rents. As shown in the appendix, for a nationwide incidence taking into account union membership and theoretical expectations, the share of the tax that falls on rents is no more than 3% (keeping wages constant) and rents would more likely benefit.

The most recent study of the United States is one by Liu and Altshuler. Their theoretical approach is difficult to interpret. As discussed in this review, there are general equilibrium effects that can shift the tax to wages, but within a closed economy with a fixed capital stock the central tendency is for the burden to be spread to all capital, but not to wages.114 Only in an open economy, where capital can flow across countries (and which would require country observations) could wage shares be estimated through this mechanism and the wage would be an economy-wide (country-wide) wage.

Generally, using a single country's data is aimed at measuring a burden that would fall on labor through the rent-sharing mechanism, except that the standard bargaining framework shows that while rents might be shared by labor, the tax on rents should not be. Liu and Altshuler never discuss a bargaining equilibrium and therefore never confront the offsetting price and income effects that tend to eliminate rent-sharing arising from taxes. In fact, at one point in their model, the wage rate becomes the numeraire (is fixed) that implies there are no industry wage differentials.

Their empirical approach is to examine how relative wage rates in each industry changed over time based on the mix of assets and the change in marginal tax rates over that period. They conclude that labor bears 60% to 80% of the tax. Why do they obtain such large effects, when theory says they should be zero or negligible? The most likely reason is because the marginal tax rate fell primarily for equipment, and those industries whose investments were more concentrated in equipment (manufacturing, transportation, construction, but especially manufacturing) probably saw slower wage growth over the period due to the decline in unions and international competition.

What Should Be Concluded About Incidence?

Although there has a resurgence of interest in direct empirical estimates of incidence, this review suggests that these reduced form empirical studies are seriously flawed, produce unreasonable estimates, are not robust (changes in specification change the results), or are inconsistent with theory, as is the case in the rent-sharing studies. Certainly, a serious problem with even the best of these studies is that the corporate tax tends to be dwarfed by the size of labor income so that it is difficult to detect this relationship or control for other factors that affect wages. The advantage of studying incidence through a general equilibrium model is that such a model can control for the factors affecting the incidence (including the limits to the effects), and, even though they are models, they are informed by empirical evidence.

Based on these models, it appears that most of the burden of the corporate tax falls on capital. The effect on capital flows without considering debt or rents suggest that labor bears 20% to 40% of the burden. If rents were 20% of total profits (and taxes) the labor share would fall to 16% to 32%. Consideration of debt could easily cause more that 100% of the burden to fall on capital. Thus the tax is a progressive one that falls on capital incomes and thus largely on higher incomes.

Economic Efficiency Issues

The traditional criticism of the corporate tax is that the tax causes distortions, and that these distortions are exacerbated by corporate tax preferences that prevent, for a given level of tax revenue, a lower tax rate. The issues discussed in this section include allocation of capital within the domestic economy, savings effects, and international capital flows.

Allocation of Capital Within the Domestic Economy

Traditionally, the efficiency concern about the corporate tax is related to the misallocation of resources between corporate and noncorporate production (including owner-occupied housing). Over time, efficiency issues have also encompassed differential taxation of the returns to assets of different physical types, and financial distortions, which affect the debt-equity ratio, payout choice, and decision to realize capital gains.

Some efficiency costs, including those that alter the mix of a firm's assets, arise not so much from the existence of a corporate tax but from its design. Table 8 captures the effects of the two most significant generally available provisions that affect tax burdens on different assets: depreciation and capital cost recovery rules and the credit for expenditures on research and development. The tax rates in this table account only for the corporate tax (that is, they do not include the benefits of deducting interest or the tax at the individual level on interest, dividends, and capital gains). They are also forward looking and marginal: they estimate the share of the return on a prospective investment that is paid in tax. If income were correctly measured and taxed that share would be the statutory rate; most assets face lower tax rates. They are presented for prior law, at a statutory 35% tax rate, with and without the production activities deduction, a provision that allowed a 9% reduction in taxable income. Under the 2017 revisions (a statutory tax rate of 21%), current law includes expensing (deducting the cost of equipment and intangible assets immediately) and permanent law returns to accelerated depreciation methods for equipment that typically allow costs of equipment to be spread over either five or seven years and reflects five-year amortization for R&D intangibles. Depreciation methods for buildings were not changed: they are deducted ratably over 39 years for most nonresidential structures, 27.5 years for residential buildings, and 20 years for farm buildings. Public utility structures are treated as equipment and expensed although they have longer lives under regular depreciation methods. Mining structures are recovered through a combination of expensing, amortization, and depletion.

Table 8. Differential Tax Rates Across Asset Types

Asset

Prior Law, No Production Deduction

Prior Law, With Production Deduction

Current Law, with Temporary Provisions

Current Law, No Temporary Provisions

Autos

32

29

0

20

Office/Computing Equipment

29

26

0

18

Trucks/Buses/Trailers

22

20

0

13

Aircraft

22

15

0

10

Construction Machinery

21

19

0

12

Mining/Oilfield Equipment

0

15

0

15

Service Industry Equipment

27

25

0

16

Tractors

24

22

0

14

Instruments

26

23

0

15

Other Equipment

26

23

0

15

General Industrial Equipment

23

21

0

13

Metalworking Machinery

23

21

0

13

Electric Transmission Equipment

23

21

0

13

Communications Equipment

18

17

0

10

Other Electrical Equipment

29

26

0

17

Furniture and Fixtures

25

22

0

14

Special Industrial Equipment 

20

18

0

12

Agricultural Equipment

21

19

0

13

Fabricated Metal

28

25

0

17

Engines and Turbines

30

27

0

18

Ships and Boats

22

20

0

12

Railroad Equipment

17

15

0

9

Mining Structures

11

10

6

6

Other Structures

33

30

20

20

Industrial Structures

36

33

22

22

Public Utility Structures

25

24

14

14

Commercial Structures

34

31

21

21

Farm Structures

26

23

15

15

Residential Structures

31

NA

16

16

Intangibles, R&D

-63.3

-63.3

-63.3

-30.2

Intangibles, Advertising

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

Intangibles, Other

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

Source: Congressional Research Service; for methodology, see CRS Report R44242, The Effect of Base-Broadening Measures on Labor Supply and Investment: Considerations for Tax Reform, by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples. The production activity deduction is estimated with a statutory tax rate that is 9% lower. Investment in R&D intangibles is negative because of the research credit which was made permanent beginning in 2016. It is estimated at 11.3%. For the magnitude of the effective credit and methodology see CRS Report R44522, A Patent/Innovation Box as a Tax Incentive for Domestic Research and Development, by Jane G. Gravelle. These tax rates are for the corporate level tax on equity and assume a 7% real discount rate and a 2% inflation rate. 

The variations within a column illustrate the distortions firms face in choosing the mix of capital within a firm. Overall the variations not only distort the mix of capital within a firm, but also the allocation of capital across different industries. Other things equal, firms that have a larger share of their capital stock in equipment or in intangibles than average will be favored.

In the aggregate, the tax rate on equipment is 0% under current law and estimated at about 14% under permanent law after expensing expires, the latter seven percentage points below the statutory tax rate.

The lowest rates are on intangible investments, such as research, advertising and investment in human capital. These costs are expensed (leading to a zero tax rate on those expenditures) and, in the case of research and development, eligible for a credit as well (leading to a negative rate). Spending on advertising is expensed and subject to a zero rate even though some advertising has future benefits. The subsidy for research investment declines in permanent law as research expenditures are deducted over five years, rather than expensed. Both current and permanent law impose the highest tax rates on structures.

Table 9 reports the types of distortions that are an artifact of the corporate tax as a separate tax. These estimates, unlike those in Table 8, take into account all levels of taxes.115 They indicate that the overall tax burden on both corporate and noncorporate investment is negative under current law and with the corporate rate lower but both small, indicating little difference. Tax rates are positive under permanent law and higher for the noncorporate sector due to the higher rate and loss of the pass-through deduction as well as the loss of expensing for equipment. Within the corporate sector, in addition to asset differences, there is a large differential with respect to debt versus equity finance; a large differential also exists for the noncorporate sector. The aggregate tax burden on debt is negative, whereas equity is taxed at a positive rate. Rates are higher for the noncorporate sector, due both to the higher statutory rate and the tendency of the noncorporate sector to hold more highly taxed assets. Shareholder taxes do not add much to the corporate tax burden due largely to the significant share of tax exempt investors, and, to a lesser extent, the lower tax rates applied to capital gains and dividends and the failure to realize about half of capital gains. If economic income were measured correctly, interest would be subject to the individual income tax rate. Debt is subsidized at the firm level, however, because nominal interest is deducted (including the inflation premium) while profits before this deduction are effectively taxed at a rate below the statutory rate on real income. The offsetting effect of taxing interest to creditors is small because most interest is not subject to tax. The overall corporate tax rate at the firm level, which would be relevant to the international allocation of capital is -5.4% under current law and 3.0% under permanent law.

Table 9. Effective Tax Rates by Sector and Type of Finance

Sector

Prior Law

Current Law, with Temporary Provisions

Current Law, no Temporary Provisions

All Business

12.5

-2.0

13.1

Corporate Business

9.6

-2.8

5.2

— Debt

-44.0

-42.2

-21.1

— Equity

22.4

6.2

13.8

Noncorporate business

16.4

0.9

16.7

— Debt

-28.1

-42.5

-28.3

— Equity

25.3

10.6

25.3

Owner Occupied Housing

-9.0

3.9

-9.0

Economy Wide

3.6

1.6

3.0

Source: See CRS Report R44242, The Effect of Base-Broadening Measures on Labor Supply and Investment: Considerations for Tax Reform, by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples for detailed assumptions. Assumptions include a 7% return to equity, a 7.5% nominal interest rate and a 2% inflation rate. The rates exclude inventories, which are generally not sensitive to tax rates; overall rates would rise to 2.7% and 3.9% if inventories are included, since they are taxed at relatively high tax rates. The noncorporate tax rate is 30% under current law and 33% under permanent law, based on information from the Congressional Budget Office. The reduction in benefits for real property taxes and mortgage interest due to the temporary provisions of the 2017 tax revision were based on the percentage reduction in itemized deductions from 2017 to 2018 which reduced the share itemized from 94% to 46% for real property taxes and 61% for mortgage interest.

Evidence on the size of this distortion is limited, but since there appears to be limited substitution between debt and equity, it is probably less than 5% of corporate tax revenue.116 Some simple measures, however, could significantly reduce this distortion (such as indexing interest payments for inflation). Lower corporate tax rates also reduce the subsidy for debt, but also reduce tax rates on equity.

The distortion that has probably received the most attention in the past by those studying the corporate tax is the misallocation of capital between the corporate and noncorporate sectors. One source of the distortion arising from the corporate tax system was the taxation of corporate business plant and equipment at around 30%, whereas unincorporated business is taxed at only 20%. These estimates predate the inclusion of intangible assets that are uncommon in the noncorporate sector. They were also estimated at a time when a larger share of shareholders was taxable and thus would be smaller even under the law prior to the 2017 tax changes. The higher corporate tax also contributes to a larger wedge between corporate production and owner-occupied housing, which is generally taxed at a negligible rate. The magnitude of the estimated distortion produced by having a separate corporate tax varies depending on the model used and ranges from less than 10% of corporate tax revenue to about a third.117 Because the deadweight loss varies with the square of the tax rate, the recent decline in the differential due to lower tax rates on dividends and capital gains suggests the distortion relative to revenue would be smaller — probably no more than 4% to 7% of revenue, or perhaps even less taking into account intangibles and the increase in tax exempt shareholders.118 Because the difference has narrowed further, the welfare loss is likely to be negligible.

A distortion not captured in Table 9 is the one that affects corporate payouts. Given that appreciation in stock values is not taxed until realized, there is a benefit to retaining earnings. There is a dispute about what determines payout ratios and what the consequences of the tax are, but, in general, the welfare cost is small. Some distortion also exists due to the lock-in effect for capital gains realizations.119

Considering all of these distortions together, they are probably no more than 5% of corporate tax revenues, a magnitude that could be considered as a significant component of the burden of the tax. However, given the revenue needs of the government, there would also be distortions, perhaps smaller, associated with alternative taxes. Ways to reduce these distortions may, however, be worth considering.

Savings Effects

Much of the 2007 Treasury study's discussion emphasized effects on savings although this is not normally the focus of efficiency concerns about the corporate income tax. This distortion is not unique to corporate income taxes, but occurs with all capital income taxes. There are many difficulties with analyzing this issue. The first is that, as noted above in the discussion about the potential effect of savings on the wage rate, the economic distortion depends on the behavioral response of savings to tax changes, and what tax replaces them. Some economists have a strong view that taxes on the rate of return are always distorting, but these views are based on dynamic infinite-horizon models that may not be very realistic. With life-cycle models, the distortions depend on what revenue substitute is provided; substituting taxes on wages for taxes on capital, the most likely substitute in the U.S. tax system, could potentially increase distortions, depending on the responses in the models.120 In models of bounded rationality, where savings are based on rules of thumb such as fixed shares of income or fixed targets, there is no response, or only an income effect, which would not produce a distorting effect.

International Capital Flows

Tax rules can affect the efficiency of allocation of capital around the world, and, if the U.S. rate is different from other countries, it can cause misallocations of capital121. According to a recent study, prior to the 2017 revision, the U.S. corporate tax rate was 39% compared with an average of 30% for the largest 15 countries excluding the United States and an average of 28.4% for OECD countries excluding the United States (both weighted by output).122 For firms eligible for the U.S. production activities deductions, characteristic of most multinationals, the rate was 36.3%. The effective tax rate (taxes divided by profits) was about the same and the marginal effective tax rates much lower and about five percentage points higher than the OECD average.

The 2017 revision lowered corporate and effective marginal tax rates so that the current statutory tax rate of 27% (federal plus state and local) is similar to the OECD average of 26%; the world average is 26% as well.123 An estimate comparing the marginal effective tax rate for equipment and structures indicates that the U.S. tax rate for equipment is among the lowest of the countries compared under current law and around midpoint for permanent law, whereas the tax rate for structures higher than most.124 A composite investment is lower than most under current law and higher than most under permanent law.125

These data do not indicate the United States is a notably high-tax country with respect to investment, even under permanent law. The main source of international distortion, therefore, is probably the increased investment that occurs in low-tax and tax-haven countries because the United States and other developed countries do not tax that income at full rates. This inefficiency is not due to the corporate effective tax rate, but rather is due to the provision of a tax benefit for investment abroad.126 Under current law, the minimum tax on foreign source income (GILTI) allows a deduction for 10% of tangible assets abroad; reducing or disallowing this exemption, raising GILTI tax rates to the United States, and allowing a foreign tax credit on a per country basis would eliminate the tax favoritism toward investing abroad in lower-tax countries.

Even when tax rates diverge, the efficiency costs appear to be relatively insignificant because the evidence suggests, as noted in previous sections, limited mobility of capital as a result of varying tax rates and natural constraints of the economy.127

Potential Revisions in the Corporate Tax

A variety of potential revisions could be made to the corporate tax. Most of the current proposals would focus on revising international provisions and raising the rate, but provisions to address other preferences could be considered. The revisions discussed here include (1) broadening the corporate tax base and using the revenues to reduce the rate or to provide investment incentives, (2) correcting interest deductions and income for inflation, and (3) increasing the individual level tax to permit a lower tax at the firm level or taxing large unincorporated firms as corporations. (To provide some reference, latest projections show corporate tax revenues at $300 billion in FY2016 and projected at $429 billion in FY2027. In 2007, prior to the recession, they were $370 billion, but they were lower during and after the recession due to cyclical factors and legislative changes.)128

This section examines current tax preferences, options, and proposals to raise corporate taxes. It also discusses past proposals that remain relevant in the context of the current rules.

Corporate Tax Expenditures

The Joint Tax Committee estimates the revenue loss for certain tax expenditures. Table 10 reports the 10-largest corporate preferences by revenue costs and their size as a percentage of corporate tax revenues, which were $211.8 billion in FY2020.129 Tax expenditures are departures from a normal income tax system and are a natural starting place for considering base broadening options.

Table 10. Ten-Largest Corporate Tax Expenditures, 2020

Provision

Revenue Loss ($billions)

Revenue Loss as a Percentage of Corporate Revenues

Reduced Rate on Active Income of Controlled Foreign Corporations

45.4

21.4

Depreciation of Equipment in Excess of Alternative System

43.2

20.4

Credit for Increasing Research

13.0

6.1

Deduction for Foreign Derived Intangible Income (FDII)

12.6

5.9

Low-Income Housing Credit

9.9

4.7

Energy Credit (Section 48)

6.1

2.9

Exclusion of Interest on State and Local Bonds

5.5

2.6

Credit for Electricity Produced from Renewable Resources (Section 45)

4.4

2.1

Deferral of Gain on Non-Dealer Installment Sales

4.0

1.9

Work Opportunity Tax Credit

2.9

1.4

Source: CRS Committee Print CP10004, Tax Expenditures: Compendium of Background Material on Individual Provisions — A Committee Print Prepared for the Senate Committee on the Budget, 2020, by Jane G. Gravelle et al.

The first three provisions have already been discussed. The first is the cost of allowing the deduction for 10% of tangible assets and allowing a deduction for 10.5% of the residual under the global minimum tax provision (GILTI). The second is the expensing of equipment relative to an alternative depreciation system (i.e., a system that allows costs to be recovered more slowly than the regular permanent depreciation rules). The third is the credit for research. The fourth provision is the deduction that was allowed under the 2017 changes to equalize the treatment of the location of intangibles in the United States with the location abroad due to the deductions for GILTI. It allows a deduction after an exclusion for 10% of intangible assets. The low income housing credit allows significant credits for constructing housing that provide lower rents for low-income families. The two energy credits are targeted at alternative and renewable energy production. The state and local bond provision allows the exclusion of interest for state and local bonds, a provision that may largely benefit state and local governments. The deferral of gain on nondealer sales allows taxpayers to defer capital gains taxes. The work opportunity credit is aimed at hiring individuals who may have difficulties in finding employment.

CBO Budget Options

The Congressional Budget Office produces a set of budget options every two years. Table 11 provides the most recent options over a 10-year period, and as a percentage of revenues during that period, $3,262 billion.130 The options include an increase in the corporate tax rate. They also include a provision disallowing the last-in, first-out (LIFO) method of inventory accounting. This allows the cost of goods sold to reflect the prices of the most recently acquired goods, which reduces taxes when prices are rising. It also includes some proposals to require half of advertising costs to be deducted over a period of time. CBO's budget options also list the repeal of the low-income housing credit.

Table 11. Revenue Gain from CBO Budget Options, FY2021-FY2030

Provision

Revenue Cost $Billions

Percentage of Corporate Revenues

Increase Corporate Rate by One Percentage Point

99.3

3.0

Repeal LIFO and Other Inventory Cost Methods

60.2

1.8

Amortize Half of Advertising Costs over Five Years

65.8

2.0

Amortize Half of Advertising Costs over Ten Years

133.4

4.1

Repeal Low Income Housing Credit

44.4

1.4

Source: CBO, Options for Reducing the Deficit: 2021-2030, December 9, 2020, https://www.cbo.gov/publication/56783. 

Biden Administration's Proposals

The Biden Administration has outlined a series of corporate tax changes, and Table 12 provides revenue estimates of the major provisions.131 The first provision would increase the corporate rate from 21% to 28%.

Table 12. Estimated Revenue Gain from the Biden Administration's Corporate Tax Proposals, FY2022-FY2031

Provision

Revenue Gain $Billions

Gain as a Percent of Corporate Revenues

Increasing Corporate Tax Rate to 28%

857.8

24.6

Revising GILTI and Anti-Inversion Rules

533.5

15.3

Reform Taxation of Foreign Fossil Fuel Income

86.2

2.5

Replace Base Erosion and Anti-Abuse Tax with Shield

390.5

11.2

Eliminating FDII Deduction

123.9

3.5

Limit Foreign Tax Credits from Sales of Hybrid Entities

0.4

*

Allocate Worldwide Interest in Proportion to Earnings Share

18.6

0.5

Minimum Tax on Book Income

148.3

4.2

Eliminate Tax Preferences for Fossil Fuels

35.1

1.0

Disallow Deductions for Outshoring

0.1

*

Source: Revenue estimates are from Department of the Treasury, General Explanations of the Administration's Fiscal Year 2022 Revenue Proposals, May 2021, https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/tax-policy/revenue-proposals. Estimates of corporate tax revenues are from CBO, https://www.cbo.gov/data/budget-economic-data#3, as of February 2021.

Note: An “*” indicates a share of less than 0.05%.

A number of provisions relate to the treatment of multinationals. The second provision would raise the GILTI tax rate to 21%, eliminate the deduction for tangible assets, and impose a per country limit. This change likely accounts for most of the revenue gains (as indicated in the subsequent revenue table for congressional proposals), but the proposal also contains strengthened rules against inverted corporations (i.e., U.S. corporations that move their headquarters abroad). This proposal would treat any company in an inversion transaction where 50% or more of the stock is owned by shareholders of the previous U.S. company or where the firm is managed and controlled in the United States as a U.S. company.132 The proposal would also reform the tax treatment of foreign oil income by including foreign oil extraction income in GILTI (which is currently excluded and not subject to tax). It also changes the treatment of so-called dual capacity taxpayers, general oil and gas extraction companies to limit foreign tax credits payments to the government for the right to extract, with a minor revenue effect. The proposal repeals the FDII deduction (the revenue gain is to be used to provide domestic research incentives). It replaces the current base erosion and anti-abuse tax (BEAT) with the stopping harmful inversions and ending low-tax developments (SHIELD), which disallows deductions for payments to related firms in tax havens. It limits foreign tax credits for income from the sale of hybrid entities.133

The proposal also imposes a 15% alternative minimum tax on the book income of corporations with more than $2 billion in income; the corporation pays the larger of this alternative tax or the regular tax.

The proposal also eliminates the preferences for fossil fuels. The largest revenue gains are from eliminating the expensing of intangible drilling costs, eliminating percentage depletion for oil and gas, and repealing the enhanced oil recovery credit (including tertiary injections).134 These provisions are accompanied by a number of provisions providing incentives for clean energy.

The proposal disallows expenses for moving operations abroad (offshoring). However, the proposal would allow a credit for moving operations to the United States (inshoring).

Congressional Proposals

Several bills introduced in the 117th Congress would focus primarily on international tax issues. S. 20 (Klobuchar), S. 714 (Whitehouse), H.R. 1785 (Doggett), and S. 991 (Sanders) would increase GILTI by taxing income at ordinary rates, eliminating the deduction for tangible assets, and providing for a per-country limit on the corporate tax. Except for S. 991, which also returns the corporate rate to 35%, these proposals are the same as the Administration's proposal. S. 714, H.R. 1785, and S. 991 also have several other provisions in common. For example, they allocate interest deductions among countries based on their share of income, which is aimed at preventing firms from allocating interest deductions to the United States and out of low-taxed countries. The bills would also repeal the deduction for FDII (as does the Administration's proposal). They also along with the Administration's proposal and two more narrowly focused bills, S. 1501 (Durbin) and H.R. 2976 (Doggett), have anti-inversion rules that would treat these new firms as U.S. firms if the U.S. shareholders have more than 50% ownership or if they are managed in the United States.

The three bills also have revisions to BEAT — although different from each other and different from the Administration's proposal. The current BEAT tax rate is 10% and certain limited credits are allowed (e.g., the research credit and 80% of the low-income housing credit and the two major energy credits referenced above). The BEAT rate is scheduled to go to 12.5% and the credits disallowed. S. 991 would move immediately to these provisions. It would also reduce the BEAT exemption from $500 million to $25 million and eliminate an exemption based on the share of base erosion payments in total payments. It eliminates payments that are already included in income in other international provisions. S. 725 (Whitehouse) and H.R. 1786 (Doggett) also have BEAT provisions, but they do not accelerate the rate change and elimination of credits or remove certain payments and they reduce the exemption to $100 million. All three bills include payments that firms elect to capitalize (deduct over several years).

S. 991, S. 725, and H.R. 1786 would change the treatment of so-called dual capacity taxpayers, which would effectively treat taxes paid in countries where governments own the natural resources as deductible royalties rather than creditable taxes.

S. 991 would also tighten the rules affecting treaty shopping (going through a country that has a treaty with the United States) to enable treaty benefits for earnings in a nontreaty country.135

S. 725 and H.R. 1786 would address other areas of international corporate taxation. The proposals would treat swap payments to foreign corporations as sourced to the payor rather than the payee, which would subject swap payments sent abroad to U.S. tax. (Swaps are contracts that allow one party to take a financial position based on expected future prices, such as currency prices.) The proposals would require firms that file SEC 10-K reports to disclose actual U.S. federal, state and local, and foreign taxes paid as well as country-by-country information on revenues, taxes, assets, employees, earnings, and profits. The proposals would charge interest on installment payments for the transition tax on accumulated deferred foreign earnings (this provision is also included in S. 991). The proposals would include foreign oil-related income in Subpart F. The proposals would tax the gain on the transfer of an intangible asset to a foreign partnership. Generally, exchanges of assets in return for a share of the partnership would not be taxed. Other sections of S. 725 and H.R. 1786 are associated with international tax administration and enforcement.

Table 13 provides estimates of the international provisions in S. 991. They are estimated assuming a 21% tax rate, although S. 991 elsewhere increases the corporate tax rate to 35%; if estimated at that rate, they would yield larger revenue gains. The increase in the tax rate to 35% would presumably raise around $1.6 trillion over 10 years, based on the revenue estimate for a single percentage point in the CBO options.

Table 13. Revenue Gain from International Provisions in S. 991 (Sanders), FY2022-FY2031

Provision

Revenue Gain $Billions

Gain as a Percentage of Corporate Revenues

Revisions to GILTI (Taxing at Full Rates with Per Country Foreign Tax Credit Limit)

676.0

19.4

Allocating Worldwide Interest in Proportion to Earnings Shares

38.1

1.1

Anti-Inversion Rules and Treaty Shopping

22.2

0.6

Changes to BEAT

26.7

0.8

Dual Capacity Taxpayers

4.3

0.1

Eliminate FDII Deduction

216.8

6.2

Source: Joint Committee on Taxation, Letter to Senator Sanders March 21, 2021, https://www.sanders.senate.gov/wp-content/uploads/Corporate-Tax-Dodging-Prevention-Act-Score-of-offshore-portion.pdf. Estimates of corporate tax revenues are from CBO, https://www.cbo.gov/data/budget-economic-data#3, as of February 2021.

Note: These estimates are based on a 21% tax rate, although Senator Sanders' bill elsewhere increases the corporate tax rate to 35%.

The House Ways and Means' Build Back Better Act

Following reconciliation, the House Build Back Better Act (BBBA; H.R. 5376 ) includes a number of corporate tax revisions, many of them similar to the Biden Administration's proposals and the various congressional proposals discussed above. Table 14 lists the corporate-related provisions and their revenue gains. The proposal would raise the corporate tax to 26.5%. Most of the other revisions relate to international tax rules, as is the case with the Administration proposals and other congressional proposals.

Table 14. Revenue Gain from Corporate-Related Provisions in the House Build Back Better Act, FY2022-FY2031

Provision

Revenue Gain ($billions)

Gain as a Percentage of Corporate Revenues

Increase Corporate Rate to 26.5%, Graduate Rates, Increase Intercorporate Dividend Deduction

540.1

14.0

Allocate Worldwide Interest in Proportion to Earnings Share

34.8

0.9

Accelerate Post 2025 GILTI and FDII Deductions for Tax rates of 16.5625% and 20.7%

96.4

2.4

Eliminate One-Month Deferral in Tax Year for CFCs

21.8

0.6

Disallow Foreign Tax Credits Above Standard Rates for Taxpayers Receiving Economic Benefits

5.7

0.1

Apply Foreign Tax Credit Limit on a Per-Country Basis, Eliminate Branch Basket, Eliminate Allocation of Interest and Head Office Expenses to Foreign Source Income, Carryforward for Five Years

63.3

1.6

GILTI: Per-Country Treatment of Income and Loss, Reduce Tangible Asset Deduction from 10% to 5%, Include Foreign Oil and Gas Extraction Income (Including Shale and Tar Sands)

106.7

12.4

Increase the Share of Foreign Taxes Credited for GILTI from 80% to 95%

-39.7

-1.0

Allow Dividend Deduction for 10% Only From CFC; Largely Eliminate Downward Attribution to Determine CFC Status

0.5

Adjustments to Subpart F Foreign Base Company Sales and Service Income; Adjustments to Assign Income to Shareholders Who Received Dividends

20.6

0.5

Increase Tax Rates for BEAT to 12.5% in 2024 and 2025 and 15% after 2025; Allow Tax Credits

24.9

0.6

Limit Credit for Orphan Drug Research to First Use

2.7

0.1

Modify Treatment of Divisive Reorganizations

20.7

0.5

Modify Earnings and Profits of CFCs

4.9

0.1

Modify Common Control Rules to Include Research and Investment

16.8

0.4

Sources: Joint Committee on Taxation, “Estimated Budgetary Effects Of An Amendment In The Nature Of A Substitute To The Revenue Provisions Of Subtitles F, G, H, I, And J Of The Budget Reconciliation Legislative Recommendations Relating To Infrastructure Financing And Community Development, Green Energy, Social Safety Net, Responsibly Funding Our Priorities, And Drug Pricing, Scheduled For Markup By The Committee On Ways And Means On September 14, 2021,” JCX-42-21, September 13, 2021, https://www.jct.gov/publications/2021/jcx-42-21/. Estimates of corporate tax revenues are from CBO, https://www.cbo.gov/data/budget-economic-data#3, as of July 2021.

Under the proposal, the U.S. share of worldwide interest deductions could not exceed 110% of the U.S. share of worldwide earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization (EBITA). The proposal limits disallowed interest from either this provision or the existing 163(j) limit to a five-year carryback (not indefinitely).

BBBA accelerates the deduction for GILTI to the 37.5% now scheduled for after 2025, making the tax rate 16.5625%. It also accelerates the lower deduction for FDII, leading to a tax rate of 20.7% and allows a carryforward of unused GILTI and FDII deductions. It reduces the deduction for tangible assets from 10% to 5% and increases the share of foreign taxes credited from 80% to 95%. Foreign oil and gas extraction income would be included in GILTI. Under BBBA, GILTI income and loss applies on a per country basis (so that losses in one country could not offset gains in another country). It allows losses a one-year carryforward.

The BBBA proposal applies the foreign tax credit limit on a per-country basis for all baskets: GILTI, passive, and active (it eliminates the branch basket). It no longer allocates interest and head office costs to foreign source income (increasing the limit). Unused foreign tax credits could be carried forward for 5 years rather than 10 years and the one-year carryback would be eliminated.

The proposal increases the BEAT tax rate from 10% (12.5% after 2025) to 12.5% in 2024 and 2025, and 15% after 2025 and allows tax credits. It adds to the base payments to foreign related parties for inventory that is required to be capitalized (such as inventory to produce tangible property) and payments for inventory in excess of cost.

The proposal would also make some smaller (in terms of revenue) changes: limiting dividend deductions to dividends from controlled foreign corporations (CFCs); limiting the scope of downward attribution rules adopted in 2017 that allow control for purposes of determining CFC status to be traced up through the foreign parent to U.S. subsidiaries that are 50% owned rather than 10%; moving some income from Subpart F to GILTI; and assigning Subpart F income to shareholders who benefited from the dividend deduction.

Other changes not specific to international issues include a revision in the orphan drug credit and provisions relating to corporate reorganizations and the rules defining firms under common control.

Draft Proposal by Senators Wyden, Brown, and Warner

Senator Wyden, chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, along with Senators Brown and Warner, have proposed draft legislation that would eliminate the deemed deduction for tangible investment from GILTI.136 It would exempt income in countries with tax rates higher than the U.S. rate and impose a per country limit on foreign tax credits for the remaining countries as well as a per country limit on losses. The amount of any deduction, either GILTI or FDII, is yet to be determined, as is the share of foreign tax credits allowed (80% or more). The proposal would apply the same exclusion for countries with high tax rates and the same limit on the foreign tax credit to Subpart F income, and apply the high tax exclusion to branch income. (Currently, Subpart F income is excluded if taxes are 90% or more of the U.S. rate, with a similar rule applied through regulation to GILTI, but not to branch income. Both are eligible for credits for 100% of foreign taxes paid.)

The draft would also disallow any cost of research and stewardship (overhead costs) to be allocated to foreign source income if performed in the United States, increasing the foreign tax credit limit and creditable foreign taxes.

The income eligible for the deduction for FDII would be revised from a provision based on an estimate of intangible income to a percentage (as yet unspecified) of research costs and certain worker training costs conducted in the United States. The deduction percentages for GILTI and FDII would be equated. Eligible training costs would be defined as apprenticeship and training programs that lead to a postsecondary credential and are provided to non-highly compensated employees.

For BEAT, a higher-tier tax would be applied to base erosion payments, so that the alternative tax would be 10% of taxable income without base erosion payments plus a higher tax rate (to be determined) that would apply to the added base erosion payments. Both rates would increase by 2.5 percentage points after 2025. All domestic credits would be allowed (e.g., research, energy, and others). Additional changes are being considered to address the objectives of the Administration's SHIELD proposal.

Other Options Proposed in Prior Congresses

A number of reform proposals were made prior to the 2017 revision; some of them designed to raise revenue to finance a reduction in the corporate rate. Some of the proposals have been reflected in proposals already discussed or have been eclipsed by the 2017 tax changes. This section discusses provisions from prior tax reform proposals that have not already been mentioned.

The 2007 Treasury study, referenced above, includes a list of preferences that contains many of the major corporate tax expenditures noted above. It also singles out some more minor tax expenditures, including the exemption of credit unions ($2 billion in FY2020), percentage depletion ($0.7 billion in FY2020), and the special lower rate for Blue Cross/Blue Shield ($0.3 billion).137

In 2007, H.R. 3970 (110th Congress) was introduced by then-Chairman of the Ways and Means Committee Rangel. It would have extended the period over which the cost of acquired intangibles is recovered from 15 years to 20 years. It was estimated to gain $21 billion over the period FY2008-FY2017.138

Over several Congresses, Senator Wyden, along with cosponsors, had introduced broad tax reform proposals. In the 111th Congress, S. 3018 (cosponsored with Senator Gregg) was scored by the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT). As with other pre-2017 proposals, most of S. 3018 provisions were also made not relevant by the 2017 legislation, but several provisions remain relevant, as shown in Table 15. The largest revenue gain of those provisions was from a proposal to index interest for inflation (that is, disallow the deduction for the portion of the nominal interest rate that reflects inflation). It also disallowed advance refunding of tax exempt bonds (issuing bonds to replace expiring bond issues in advance of their expiration), eliminated percentage depletion for hard minerals as well as fossil fuels, although that expansion has a negligible revenue effect, eliminated LIFO inventory accounting but only for oil producers, applied the current inversion rules retroactively, and repealed the special tax rate for nuclear decommissioning. These provisions were relatively small.

Table 15. Relevant Corporate and Business Tax Provisions in the Wyden-Gregg Bill, S. 3018, Introduced in 2010

Provision

Average Cost FY2011-FY2020, $ billions

Index interest for inflation

16.3

Prohibition on advance refunding

1.2

Eliminate percentage depletion, capitalize intangible drilling costs and mine development costs

1.6

Repeal LIFO for large oil and gas producers, eliminate lower of cost or market inventory

0.8

Apply inversion rules retroactively to 2002

0.2

Eliminate special tax rate on nuclear decommissioning

0.1

Source: Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimate of the Revenue Effects of S. 3018, The Bipartisan Tax Fairness and Simplification Act of 2010, November 2, 2010, at http://wyden.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Score.pdf. 

In 2013, the Senate Finance Committee released discussion drafts on cost recovery and accounting that relate to corporate taxation as well as a draft on international corporate tax issues.139 These proposals were not scored. The proposals included a revision of the cost recovery provisions, introducing a new depreciation system that would slow depreciation and approximate the present value of economic depreciation. Assets would have been added to general pools rather than each vintage of investments being depreciated separately. Real property would have depreciated over 43 years.140

The Obama Administration's annual budgets also included corporate tax reform provisions, concentrated in a few areas: international provisions, insuranc e provisions, inventory accounting, and fossil fuels. Most of these provisions are no longer relevant or are included in some of the current proposals or budget options. A number of notable provisions have been included in those budgets. Some international provisions related to a rule under current and prior law that requires current taxation at full rates for certain easily shifted income called Subpart F income, named after the code section specifying these rules. One provision that eventually disappeared from the proposals was to eliminate “check the box” provisions which allow avoidance of Subpart F treatment, so that under current law this income falls in the lower taxed GILTI category.141 Another was to expand the Subpart F category to include digital income. A foreign provision was to disallow a deduction for reinsurance premiums to affiliated but foreign-owned firms. These budgets also contained two other business provisions of note. One was to limit the gain that can escape tax through like-kind exchanges (i.e., exchanges of property that avoid capital gains taxes, limited since the 2017 tax revision to real property) to a dollar amount. The other was to increase the depreciation period that costs can be recovered for noncommercial aircraft to commercial aircraft (from five years to seven years), a provision not currently relevant but that would become so when and if expensing expires.

In 2014, revenue estimates were released for the Tax Reform Act of 2014 (H.R. 1) introduced by Dave Camp, then-chairman of the Ways and Means Committee.142 This proposal repealed or revised 115 corporate-related provisions including most corporate-related tax expenditures (which are discussed above); estimates are found in a 2014 JCT document.143 As with other prior law provisions, most of the provisions in this proposal are no longer relevant under the 2017 law or are reflected in the reform proposals already presented, although the proposal did include full amortization of advertising costs rather than the half in the CBO study and also proposed not only retaining depreciation for equipment but slowing it.

Evaluating Tax Revisions

A full discussion of the economic merits of these provisions is beyond the scope of this paper, but the standard tax expenditure items are discussed in the Senate Budget Committee Print, Tax Expenditure Compendium;144 most would be regarded as provisions that lead to economic distortions.145 One possible exception is the Research and Experimentation (R&E) credit, because social returns to research and development appear higher than private returns, but many economists believe that the credit is probably poorly targeted and possibly abused. This argument also applies to expensing of research costs. Arguments could also be made that the tax exempt bond benefit is shifted to state and local governments (which can charge lower interest rates) and that these assets and revenue losses would be shifted to individuals. Further arguments could be made that the benefits of the charitable contribution deduction and the low-income housing credit ultimately accrue to charities and lower-income tenants, at least in part. Many other provisions have some support, and may, therefore, be difficult to repeal. Aside from increasing the corporate tax rate, the two most important provisions in terms of revenue are reduced taxation of foreign source income and expensing of the cost of acquiring equipment.146 Replacing expensing and the normal accelerated depreciation system with slower depreciation would raise the cost of capital. However, expensing, as well as the regular depreciation system, favors equipment over structures. This issue could be addressed by increasing the tax on equipment by extending depreciable lives and shortening depreciation periods for structures. Accelerated depreciation, including expensing, also exacerbates negative tax rates on debt financed assets because it maintains the full deduction for nominal interest while reducing (in the case of expensing, to zero) the effective tax rate on the earnings. This effect makes a case for limiting interest deductions and supports a proposal to disallow the inflation portion.147

Increasing Individual Level Taxes; Shifting Between Corporate and Individual Form

As an alternative or in addition to raising corporate revenues, the individual tax on dividends and capital gains could be increased. Because individual taxes tend to be collected regardless of where income is earned, these taxes are neutral with respect to international allocation. One approach is to reverse the 2003 tax changes that lowered rates on dividends that were previously taxed as ordinary income to the lower capital gains tax rates. Dividends and capital gains are currently subject to a top rate of 20%; the top rate for ordinary income is 37%, scheduled to rise to 39.6% after 2025.

Additional revenue could be raised by taxing capital gains at ordinary rates. The tax expenditure estimate for lower rates for capital gains and dividends is $1,148.5 billion, although this estimate includes tax on assets other than corporate stock and does not account for behavioral responses. Based on the JCT revenue estimating methodology, the amount of additional revenue would be significantly constrained by the behavioral effect on realizations, although there is disagreement on this effect, including a recent study that found a much smaller effect.148 This behavioral response would be considerably reduced if taxing capital gains at death, which has been included in a number of proposals, and would also raise additional revenue.149 The Biden budget proposals would tax gains and dividends of taxpayers with $1 million or more of income for married couples and $500,000 of income for singles at the top ordinary rate (currently at 37% but raised elsewhere in the proposal to the prior rate of 39.6%). It would also tax capital gains in excess of $2 million for married couples and $1 million for singles when transferred at death or by gift. (Transfers to spouses or charities would be excluded.) This provision is projected to raise $332 billion over 10 years. The BBBA would increase the top capital gains rate from 20% to 25%, estimated to raise $124 billion over 10 years.

A more extensive proposal, taxing capital gains on an accrual basis would yield dramatically more revenue.150 This type of change would also eliminate distortions arising from payout policies and realization responses. Additional revenue could be achieved by taxing nonprofits on earnings from corporate shares as income to pension and retirement funds and as unrelated business income to nonprofits, which is important because over half the stock of U.S. firms is owned by these tax exempt shareholders. Another provision that might be used to raise revenues if the tax on the corporate sector is raised substantially is to tax the increasing number of large pass-throughs as corporations, for example, by taxing any entity that benefits from limited liability as a corporation. (Publicly traded partnerships, with some exceptions, are already taxed as corporations.) How much, if any, revenue that change would raise depends on any changes in taxation of dividends and capital gains and the individual and corporate income rates.

Conclusion

On the whole, many of the concerns expressed about the corporate tax leading up to the 2017 rate cut appear not to stand up under empirical examination. The claims that behavioral responses could cause revenues to rise if rates were cut do not hold up on either a theoretical basis or an empirical basis. Studies that purport to show a revenue-maximizing tax rate of 30% contain econometric errors that produce biased and inconsistent results; when those problems are corrected the results disappear. Evidence from empirically driven models indicate that the corporate tax largely falls on labor. Reduced form empirical studies that are cited as providing direct evidence showing that the burden of the corporate tax actually falls on labor generally yield unreasonable results and prove to suffer from econometric flaws that also lead to a disappearance of the results when corrected. Similarly, claims that high U.S. tax rates will create problems for the United States in a global economy suffer from a misrepresentation of the U.S. tax rate compared with other countries and are less important when capital is imperfectly mobile, as it appears to be.

Although these arguments appear to rely on questionable data, the traditional concerns about the corporate tax appear valid. Many economists believe that the tax is still needed as a backstop to individual tax collections, even though it results in some economic distortions. These economic distortions, however, have declined substantially over time as corporate rates and shares of output have fallen. A number of changes could reduce these distortions.


Appendix A first page

[Editor's Note: The reference mark for footnote 151 appears in the image above.]

Appendix A - Second Page


Appendix B - First Page

[Editor's Note: The reference mark for footnote 152 appears in the image above.]

[Editor's Note:The reference mark for footnote 153 appears in the image above.]

[Editor's Note: The reference mark for footnote 154 appears in the image above.]

Appendix B - Second Page

[Editor's Note: The reference mark for footnote 155 appears in the image above.]

[Editor's Note:The reference mark for footnote 156 appears in the image above.]

Appendix B - Third Page


Appendix C - First Page

Appendix C - Second Page


Appendix D - First Page

Appendix D - Second Page

Appendix D - Third Page

Appendix D - Fourth Page; and Author Information, Acknowledgments and Disclaimer

FOOTNOTES

1U.S. Department of the Treasury's Office of  ax Analysis, The Case for Responsible Business Tax Reform, January 2017, https://home.treasury.gov/system/files/131/Report-Responsible-Business-Tax-Reform-2017.pdf.

2Richard Rubin, “Who Ultimately Pays for Corporate Taxes? The Answer May Color the Republican Overhaul,” Wall Street Journal, August 8, 2017. The paper referenced is Céline Azémar and Glenn Hubbard, “Country Characteristics and the Incidence of Capital Income Taxes on Wages: An Empirical Assessment,” Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 48, iss. 5 (December 2015), pp. 1762-1802.

3Robert Farley, “Who Benefits from Corporate Tax Cut, The Wire, September 7, 2017 at http://www.factcheck.org/2017/09/benefits-corporate-tax-cut/. The papers cited are William C. Randolph, International Burdens of the Corporate Tax, Congressional Budget Office, Working Paper no. 2006-09, August 2006; Kevin A. Hassett and Aparna Mathur, “A Spatial Model of Corporate Tax Incidence,” Applied Economics, vol. 47, no. 3 (2015), pp. 1350-1365; and Li Liu and Rosanne Altshuler, Measuring the Burden of a Corporate Tax Under Imperfect Competition, Oxford Working Paper no. 11/05. A version was subsequently published in the National Tax Journal, vol. 66, no. 1 (September 2013), pp. 215-237.

4Gordon Gray, “ Corporate Tax Reform and How It affects Economic Growth, American Action Forum,” April 18, 2017, https://www.americanactionforum.org/research/corporate-tax-reform-affects-economic-growth-2/. Kevin A. Hassett, “The Cure for Wage Stagnation,” Wall Street Journal, August 14, 2016, at http://www.aei.org/publication/the-cure-for-wage-stagnation/.

5Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, “Corporate Rat e Cuts Are a Poor Way to Help the Economy and Most Workers-and Could Hurt Them,” June 9, 2017; Kimberly Clausing, “In Search of Corporate Tax Incidence,” Tax Law Review, vol. 65 (2012), pp. 433-471, http://piketty.pse.ens.fr/files/Clausing2012.pdf.

6This report was initially prepared to discuss some of the issues raised at that time and has been updated to follow the developments in research, especially concerning whether the tax burden falls on capital or labor.

7Tax Policy Center, Simple, Fair, and Pro-Growth: Proposals to Fix America's Tax System, November 2005, at http://www.taxreformpanel.gov/.

8Henry M. Paulson Jr., “Our Broken Corporate Tax Code,” The Wall Street Journal, July 19, 2007.

9U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Treasury Tax Conference on Business Taxation and Global Competitiveness: Background Paper,” July 30, 2007, at https://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Documents/07230%20r.pdf.

10R. Glenn Hubbard, “The Corporate Tax Myth,” The Wall Street Journal, July 26, 2007. The paper was the first version of the Hassett and Mathur study: Kevin A. Hassett and Aparna Mathur, Taxes and Wages, American Enterprise Institute, working paper, March 6, 2006, presented at a conference of the American Enterprise Institute on May 2, 2006. The reference to Michael Devereux apparently refers to a paper also presented at the American Enterprise Institute Symposium.

11This summary and other references to the issues discussed at the conference are based on two detailed media accounts of the conference: Heidi Glenn, “Business Leaders would Give Up Tax Breaks for Lower Rates,” Tax Notes, July 30, 2007, pp. 324-327, and Joanne M. Weiner, “U.S. Corporate Tax Reform: All Talk, No Action,” Tax Notes, August 27, 2007, pp. 716-728.

12Statement released by the Honorable Charles B. Rangel, chairman, Ways and Means Committee, July 26, 2007.

13See Jeffrey H. Birnbaum, “Democrat Overhaul of Taxes: Rangel Would Annul AMT, Shift Burden,” Washington Post, October 26, 2007, p. D1.

14N. Gregory Mankiw, “The Problem with the Corporate Tax,” New York Times, June 2, 2008. For empirical evidence on incidence he cites an empirical study by Wiji Aralampalam, Michael P. Devereux, and Giorgia Maffini, The Direct Incidence of Corporate Income Tax on Wages, Oxford University Center for Business Taxation, May, 2008. For empirical evidence on the feedback effects on revenue, he cites Alex Brill and Kevin Hassett, Revenue Maximizing Corporate Income Taxes, American Enterprise Institute, Working Paper no. 137, July 31, 2007.

15See “Leader Cantor Unveils Pro-Growth Economic Plan at Stanford University,” press release, March 21, 2011, http://majorityleader.house.gov/newsroom/2011/03/embargoed-leader-cantor-unveils-pro-growth-economic-plan-at-stanford-university.htm and “Obama Backs Corporate Tax Cut If Won't Raise Deficit,” Bloomberg, January 25, 2011, http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2011-01-26/obama-backs-cut-in-u-s-corporate-tax-rate-only-if-it-won-t-affect-deficit.html. For proposals in the deficit reduction plans, see CRS Report R41970, Addressing the Long-Run Budget Deficit: A Comparison of Approaches, by Jane G. Gravelle and CRS Report R41641, Reducing the Budget Deficit: Tax Policy Options, by Molly F. Sherlock.

16See CRS Report R44638, Corporate Tax Integration and Tax Reform, by Jane G. Gravelle.

17Although the border adjustments that led it to be a domestic consumption tax appear ed no longer on the table, the proposal was similar in its effects on investment to a consumption tax in that it had expensing and disallowed interest deductions, which means it did not tax the return to marginal investments. For a more detailed discussion, see CRS Report R44823, The “Better Way” House Tax Plan: An Economic Analysis, by Jane G. Gravelle. For a discussion of the plan under development, see Jonathan Curry, Luca Gattoni-Celli, and Asha Glover, “'Big Six' Tout Tax Reform Unity, Drop Border Tax,” Tax Analysts, July 28, 2017, http://www.taxanalysts.org/content/big-6-tout-tax-reform-unity-drop-border-tax.

18For a summary of the 2017 changes, see CRS Report R45092, The 2017 Tax Revision (P.L. 115-97): Comparison to 2017 Tax Law, coordinated by Molly F. Sherlock and Donald J. Marples. For a detailed explanation of the international changes, see CRS Report R45186, Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L. 115-97), by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples.

19The data discussed in this paragraph are taken from Jane G. Gravelle, “The Corporate Tax: Where Has it Been and Where is it Going?,” National Tax Journal, vol. 57 (December 2004), pp. 903-923; U.S. Congressional Budget Office (CBO), Historical Data, http://cbo.gov/publication/42911; CBO, The Budget and Economic Outlook, Fiscal Years 2012-2022, http://cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/01-31-2012_Outlook.pdf; and CBO, The Budget and Economic Outlook, Fiscal Years 2017-2027, https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/115th-congress-2017-2018/reports/52370-outlookonecolumn.pdf and supplementary data at https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#2. More recent data and projections are at https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#2.

20See CRS Report RS21706, Historical Effective Marginal Tax Rates on Capital Income, by Jane G. Gravelle and CRS Report R45186, Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L. 115-97), by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples for current effective tax rates. The 63% rate may be slightly overstated because that rate does not capture the effect of intangible investments. Intangible investmen ts were taxed at zero (but not at negative rates since there was no research tax credit). If the share of intangibles were the same as currently (23%), the tax rate in 1953 would be 57%; however, intangibles were likely less important at that time. These tax rates are for equity investments.

21See also CRS Report R42113, Reasons for the Decline in Corporate Tax Revenues, by Mark P. Keightley, which traces the decline in average effective tax rates, the reduction in the share of business income represented by the corporate sector, and the falling rate of profit.

22Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income, Integrated Business Data, Table 1, at https://www.irs.gov/uac/soi-tax-stats-integrated-business-data.

23The law lowered the top rate to 15%, although subsequent legislation taxed very high-income individuals' dividends and capital gains at 20%. In addition, a 3.8% additional tax was enacted in 2010, applying to dividends and capital gains.

24The deduction is phased out at high income levels for personal service businesses and, for other businesses subject to the phase out limited to a share of wages or a combination of wages and depreciable assets. See CRS Report R46650, Section 199A Deduction: Economic Effects and Policy Options, by Gary Guenther for further information.

25The 3.8% additional tax on high-income individuals applies to all earnings of proprietors and general partners, because they are classified as labor income for purposes of the payroll tax, as well as the labor share of income in any other unincorporated business. Active participants in Subchapter S firms with a small amount of labor income could have lower taxes in the Subchapter S form approaching the ordinary income tax rate.

26Excise taxes can be set at more than 100% and still yield revenue. Taxes on real capital income in excess of 100% can also yield revenues because inflation is an implicit tax on the holding of cash.

27Peter Baker, Arthur Laffer's theory on Tax cuts Comes to Life Once More, New York Times, April 25, 2017, https://www.nytimes.com/2017/04/25/us/politics/white-house-economic-policy-arthur-laffer.html.

28Kevin A. Hassett, “Art Laffer, Righter Than Ever,” National Review, February 13, 2006, https://www.aei.org/articles/art-laffer-righter-than-ever/.

29Another discussion of this issue appeared in an editorial in The Wall Street Journal, which also presented a chart with a number of OECD countries on it. (“We're Number One, Alas,” The Wall Street Journal, July 13, 2007, p. A12.) In this chart, the editors simply drew a curve, which passed through a couple of points. There was no statistical fitting to the data and no informative value to such an analysis; moreover the two points through which the freehand curve was drawn were questionable: one was the United Arab Emirates with no tax, which is neither a typical country nor in the OECD, and the other was Norway, whose corporate tax revenue tends to be high because of oil. The bulk of the data showed no obvious trend. For insight into how this graph was viewed by economists, see Brad DeLong, an economist at Stanford and author of a website, Brad DeLong's Daily Journal, who titled his entry “Most Dishonest Wall Street Journal Editorial Ever.” There was some perception, which was incorrect, that this graph was prepared byKevin Hassett because he was mentioned as a source, but that was not the case; he provided some of the data (personal communication with Kevin Hassett). Based on data provided by one of the correspondents in that debate, a simple regression of corporate share on tax and tax squared showed no significant coefficients for tax variables, indicating no relationship: http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2007/07/most-dishonest-.html.

30Kimberly A. Clausing, “Corporate Tax Revenues in OECD Countries,” International Tax and Public Finance, vol. 14. (April 2007), pp. 115-133.

31Michael P. Devereux, Developments in the Taxation of Corporate Profit in the OECD Since 1965: Rates, Bases and Revenues, May 2006 presented at a conference of the Alliance for Competitive Taxation and the American En terprise Institute, June 2, 2006.

32Alex Brill and Kevin Hassett, Revenue Maximizing Corporate Income Taxes, American Enterprise Institute, Working Paper no. 137, July 31, 2007.

33Jack M. Mintz, 2007 Tax Competitiveness Report: A Call for comprehensive Tax Reform, C.D. Howe Institute, No. 254, September 2007.

34Hence, most of the variation is across countries, which, as discussed below, is a potentially serious problem.

35An invariant tax base would occur when both production and utility were of the Cobb Do uglas form, which is unitary factor substitution elasticities and unitary product substitution elasticities. At 100% tax rate a corner solution would be presumably be reached where the corporate sector would entirely disappear, but only at that extreme rat e would such an effect occur.

36Brill and Hassett, Revenue Maximizing Corporate Income Taxes, p. 6.

37See Ruud de Mooij, The Tax Elasticity of Corporate Debt: A Synthesis of Size and Variations, International Monetary Fund, Working Paper no. WP-11-95, April, 2011, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp1195.pdf.

38The Treasury study provides data on the growth over time in unincorporated business forms and suggests that the large share of this income in the United States relative to other countries is due to the ability to avoid the corporate tax and still retain limited liability in the United States. The growth in Subchapter S income (partnerships that can elect to be taxed as corporations) corresponds to increasing limits on the number of permissible shareholders, and the growth in partnership income to the growth in the number of states allowing limited liability companies that do not fall under the corporate tax. Proprietorship income shares have changed very little. In any case, this growth occurred during a period when the corporate tax was constant or falling.

39Jane G. Gravelle, “Policy Options to Address Profit Shifting: Carrots or Sticks?” Tax Notes, July 4, 2016, pp. 121-134. Even the largest elasticities suggested that a dollar of revenue loss would be offset by only nine cents due to induced profit shifting; the smallest suggested only one cent.

40See Joint Committee on Taxation, U.S. International Tax Policy: Overview and Analysis, JCX-16R-21, April 19, 2021, https://www.jct.gov/CMSPages/GetFile.aspx?guid=aa66e305-74cc-40bc-acad-55bb3e6d5971, which compared 2017 and 2018 tax data; and Testimony of Kimberly A. Clausing, Deputy Assistant Secretary, Tax Analysis, Before the Senate Committee on Finance, U.S. Department of the Treasury, March 21, 2021, https://home.treasury.gov/news/press-releases/jy0079, which compared data from 2000 through 2019 from the Commerce Department.

41CRS Report R41743, International Corporate Tax Rate Comparisons and Policy Implications, by Jane G. Gravelle

42See Alex Brill and Kevin A. Hassett, Revenue-Maximizing Corporate Income Taxes: The Laffer Curve in OECD Countries. The authors obtained data from the same sources as Brill and Hassett.

43The terms biased and inconsistent are technical statistical terms. See Appendix B for a description and the consequences of these problems, and the statistical definitions for biased and inconsistent.

44See Kimberly A. Clausing, “Corporate Tax Revenues in OECD Countries.” The authors thank Kimberly Clausing for providing her data.

45Clausing included two variables in her analysis indicating the type of corporate tax system that do not vary over time for a country. The coefficients of these variables are not identified when using the fixed effect estimation method, which is probably why she estimated the coefficients using OLS. While she obtained coefficient estimates for these two variables, the estimates are biased and inconsistent.

46Laura Kawano & Joel Slemrod, “ How Do Corporate Tax Bases Change When Corporate Tax Rates Change? With Implications for the Tax Rate Elasticity of Corporate Tax Revenues,” International Tax and Public Finance, vol. 23, no. 3 (June 2016), pp. 401-433.

47For reviews, see Robert Chirinko, “Investment Tax Credits,” in The Encyclopedia of Taxation and Tax Policy, ed. by Joseph J. Cordes, Robert D. Ebel and Jane G. Gravelle, Washington, DC, the Urban Institute, 2005, pp. 226-229 and Kevin A. Hassett and R. Glenn Hubbard, “Tax Policy and Business Investment, ” Handbook of Public Economics (New York: Elsiever, 2002), pp. 1293-1343.

48Simeon Djankov, Tim Ganser, Caralee McLiesh, Rita Ramalho, and Andrei Shleifer, “The Effect of Corporate Taxes on Investment and Entrepreneurship,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper no. 13756, January 2008. This paper was subsequently published in the American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 2, pp. 31-64.

49Jane G. Gravelle and Kent A. Smetters, “Does the Open Economy Assumption Really Mean That Labor Bears the Burden of a Capital Income Tax?” Advances in Economic Policy and Analysis, vol. 6, no. 1, 2006

50Richard Rubin, “Who Ultimately Pays for Corporate Taxes? The Answer May Color the Republican Overhaul,” Wall Street Journal, August 8, 2017. The paper referenced is Céline Azémar and Glenn Hubbard, “Country Characteristics and the Incidence of Capital Income Taxes on Wages: An Empirical Assessment,” Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 48, iss. 5 (December 2015), pp. 1762-1802.

51CRS Report RL33285, Tax Reform and Distributional Issues, by Jane G. Gravelle (out of print, but available from the author upon request).

52In the past, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), the Department of the Treasury, and the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center attributed 100% of the tax to capital income. In the past few years, all three organizations have moved to assigning a small share to labor income. CBO assigns 25%, the Department of the Treasury 18%, and the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center 20%. The Department of Treasury and the Tax Policy center assign a large share of the tax to stockholders based on the idea that a large share of income is supra-normal returns. This share is based in part on an estimate of the share of the corporate tax that is above a risk-free return. While some part of this return may be rent, it probably also largely reflects risk premiums. There is, however, little justification for assigning the part of a return due to anticipated risk as an “excess return” since such returns compensate for risk-taking. With risk and imperfect loss offset, the tax on the risk premium falls in part in the same way as the normal return, in part on taxpayers to the extent the tax reduces the variance of return but increases variance in revenues, and to some ext ent disappears because the government is less risk-adverse than individuals. The CBO allocates the tax based on results from general equilibrium models, modified for certain issues such as debt finance and rents. For further explanation, see CBO, The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2008 and 2009, http://cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/43373-06-11-HouseholdIncomeandFedTaxes.pdf; Julie-Anne Cronin, Emily Y. Lin, Laura Power, and Michael Cooper , Distributing the Corporate Income Tax: Revised U.S. Treasury Methodology, Office of Tax Analysis Technical Paper 5, May 2012. This paper was subsequently published in the National Tax Journal, March 2013, vol. 66, no. 1, pp. 239-262, https://www.ntanet.org/NT J/66/1/ntj-v66n01p239-62-distributing-corporate-income-tax.pdf; Jim Nunns, How the TPC Distributes the Corporate Income Tax, Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/ UploadedPDF/412651-Tax-Model-Corporate-Tax-Incidence.pdf.

53It is not clear which of Harberger's papers is being referred to, but it is presumably the more recent one: Arnold C. Harberger, Corporate Tax Incidence: What is Known, Unknown, and Unknowable, University of California, 2006. This paper was presented at a conference at Rice University in 2006, and subsequently published as in Fundamental Tax Reform: Issues, Choices, and Implications, ed. John W. Diamond and George R. Zodrow, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 2008.

54The paper in question is not an official CBO paper but rather a working paper by William Randolph. William C. Randolph, International Burdens of the Corporate Tax, CBO, Working Paper no. 2006-09, August 2006.

55Kevin A. Hassett and Aparna Mathur, Taxes and Wages, American Enterprise Institute, Working Paper, April 2008.

56Rachel Alison Felix, Passing the Burden: Corporate Tax Incidence in Open Economies, November 2006. This paper was a dissertation essay, University of Michigan.

57Mihir A. Desai, C. Fritz Foley, and James R. Hines Jr., Labor and Capital shares of the corporate Tax Burden: International Evidence. Prepared for the International Tax forum and Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center conference on Who Pays the Corporate Tax in an Open Economy, December 18, 2007.

58Wiji Aralampalam, Michael P. Devereux, and Giorgia Maffini, The Direct Incidence of Corporate Income Tax on Wages, Oxford University Center for Business Taxation, May, 2008. A revised version was subsequently released in March, 2011. The paper was published in the European Economic Review, vol. 56 (2012), pp. 1038-1054.

59Robert Farley, “Who Benefits from Corporate Tax Cut, The Wire,” September 7, 2017, at http://www.factcheck.org/2017/09/benefits-corporate-tax-cut/. The last study is Li Liu and Rosanne Altshuler, Measuring the Burden of a Corporate Tax Under Imperfect Competition, Oxford Working Paper no. 11/05, subsequently published in the National Tax Journal, vol. 66, no. 1 (March 2013), pp. 215-238.

60Jane G. Gravelle and Kent A. Smetters, “Does the Open Economy Assumption Really Mean That Labor Bears the Burden of a Capital Income Tax?” Advances in Economic Policy and Analysis, vol. 6, no. 1, 2006.

61Jennifer Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: Review of General Equilibrium Estimates and Analysis, CBO, Working Paper no. 2010-03, May 2010, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/115xx/doc11519/05-2010-Working_Paper-Corp_Tax_Incidence-Review_of_Gen_Eq_Estimates.pdf. A version of this paper was published in the National Tax Journal, vol. 16, no. 1 (March 2013), pp. 185-215.

62Note that a lower ability to substitute capital for labor in production, while increasing the burden on labor, reduces the capital inflow, leads to a smaller increase in output, and a higher rev enue maximizing tax rate.

63See Megan Dunn and James Walker, Union Membership in the United States, Bureau of Labor Statistics, September 2016, https://www.bls.gov/spotlight/2016/union-membership-in-the-united-states/pdf/union-membership-in-the-united-states.pdf.

64Harry Grubert and John Mutti, “International Aspects of Corporate Tax Integration: The Role of Debt and Equity Flows,” National Tax Journal, vol. 47, March, 1994, pp. 111-133.

65See CRS Report R41743, International Corporate Tax Rate Comparisons and Policy Implications, by Jane G. Gravelle.

66Jennifer Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: Review of General Equilibrium Estimates and Analysis, CBO, Working Paper no. 2010-03, May 2010, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/115xx/doc11519/05-2010-Working_Paper-Corp_Tax_Incidence-Review_of_Gen_Eq_Estimates.pdf.

67These issues surrounding savings are discussed in greater detail in CRS Report R42111, Tax Rates and Economic Growth, by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples; CRS Report RL32517, Distributional Effects of Taxes on Corporate Profits, Investment Income, and Estates, by Jane G. Gravelle and Sean Lowry (available upon request from the author); CRS Report RL33545, The Advisory Panel's Tax Reform Proposals, by Jane G. Gravelle; and CRS Report RL33482, Saving Incentives: What May Work, What May Not, by Thomas L. Hungerford, which is available upon request. The recognition that replacement of capital income taxes by wage taxes in a life cycle model could have little effect on savings or contract them can be found in numerous simulation studies, for example, Alan Auerbach and Laurence Kotlikoff, Dynamic Fiscal Policy (Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, 1987).

68This study is one of a number of empirical studies that try to estimate incidence from a direct examination of wages (as opposed to embedding capital flow and other elasticities into a model). For other reviews of these studies see William M. Gentry, A Review of the Evidence on the Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax, U.S. Department of Treasury, Office of Tax Analysis, Working Paper no. 101, December 2007, http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/ tax-policy/tax-analysis/Documents/ota101.pdf; Jennifer C. Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and Analysis, CBO, Working Paper no. 2011-01, June 2011, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/122xx/doc12239/ 06-14-2011-CorporateTaxIncidence.pdf; and Kimberly A. Clausing, In Search of Corporate Tax Incidence, September 2011, Presented at a Conference of the American Tax Policy Institute, http://americantaxpolicyinstitute.org/15papers/ Clausing%20ATPI.pdf.

69To convert an elasticity into an incidence measure, the coefficient should be multiplied by the ratio of labor income to the corporate tax. Two other studies using cross-country data have examined the incidence of the tax on labor income. Passing the Burden: Corporate Tax Incidence in Open Economies, by Rachel Alison Felix, November 2006, finds smaller effects than Hassett and Mathur, but ones that are still too large to be predicted by a theoretical model. This study has problems similar to those that are discussed subsequently and, in addition, do not control for country fixed effects.

70Hassett and Mathur, Taxes and Wages. The authors are grateful to Kevin Hassett and Aparna Mathur for providing their data. Several of the countries only have data for shorter periods.

71Their independent or explanatory variables take their v alue from the beginning of the five-year period over which wages are averaged. It should also be noted that Hassett and Mathur calculate the five-year average with nominal wages (that is, they are not corrected for inflation).

72See Appendix B for a description of the estimation method. Visual inspection of the Hassett and Mathur data uncovered some errors with their five-year averages of wage rates — some averages were based on six years of data and others were based on less than five years of data. The authors corrected the errors so that each five-year period for each country contains five years of data. Some of the averages are based on less than five years of data because of missing values in the wage series; most of the missing values are in the 2001 to 2005 period.

73The specific test of statistical significance of the coefficient estimates is the t-test. This is a test of whether or not the estimate is equal to zero (the null hypothesis is the estimate is equal to zero). The significance level indicates the risk of rejecting the null hypothesis when it is, in fact, true. A significance level of 5% indicates that the null hypothesis will be inadvertently rejected only 5% of the time. Significance levels commonly used in empirical social science work are the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels.

74Including the lagged values of the corporate tax rate allows the tax rates for the previous five years to individually have an impact on wages. All tax rates are entered into the model in logarithms.

75The authors obtain the same estimation results when the exchange rate is used to convert wage rates to U.S. dollars — the method used by Hassett and Mathur.

76Kevin A. Hassett and Aparna Mathur, “Spatial Tax Competition and Domestic Wages,” December, 2010, http://www.aei.org/docLib/SpatialTaxCompetitionandDomesticWages.pdf. A version of this paper was published as “A Spatial Model of Corporate Tax Incidence,” Applied Economics, vol. 47, no. 3 (2015), pp. 1350-1365.

77These generic problems are discussed by Jennifer C. Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and Analysis, CBO, Working Paper no. 2011-01, June 2011, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/122xx/doc12239/ 06-14-2011-CorporateTaxIncidence.pdf.

78Thus authors indicate that the fall in wages is $4, a lower but still implausible number. However, they calculate this incidence with the ratio of wages to taxes in the manufacturing sector, which is much smaller. Effects of the corporate tax on wages are, however, economy wide effects that should lower wages in the other sectors, including noncorporate sectors.

79Rachael Alison Felix, Passing the Burden: Corporate Tax Incidence in Open Economies, November 2006. This paper was a dissertation essay at the University of Michigan.

80Mihir A. Desai, C. Fritz Foley, and James R. Hines Jr., “Labor and Capital Shares of the Corporate Tax Burden: International Evidence,” prepared for the International Tax Policy Forum and Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center conference on Who Pays the Corporate Tax in an Open Economy?, December 18, 2007.

81His remarks were made at a seminar at the American Enterprise Institute, March 17, 2008.

82The coefficient must be close to twice the standard error to be statistically significant; thus the result from the unrestricted regression showed no relationship between taxes and wages.

83Kimberly A. Clausing, “In Search of Corporate Tax Incidence,” November 2011.

84Jennifer C, Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and Analysis, CBO, Working Paper no. 2011-01, June 2011, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/122xx/doc12239/06-14-2011-CorporateTaxIncidence.pdf.

85Nelly Exbrayat and Benny Geys, “Economic Integration, Corporate Tax Incidence and Fiscal Compensation,” The World Economy, 2016, pp. 1792-1811. For a semi-elastic estimate, the coefficient should be multiplied by labor income and divided by the tax and the average wage.

86R. Alison Felix, “Do State Corporate Income Taxes Reduce Wages?” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, vol. 94, no. 9, 2009.

87Jennifer C, Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and Analysis, CBO, Working Paper 2011-01, June 2011, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/122xx/doc12239/06-14-2011-CorporateTaxIncidence.pdf.

88R. Alison Felix, and James R. Hines, Corporate Taxes and Union Wages in the United States, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper no. 15263, August, 2009.

89Robert Carroll, Corporate Taxes and Wages: Evidence from the 50 States, Tax Foundation, Working Paper no. 8, August 2009, http://www.taxfoundation.org/files/wp8.pdf.

90Juan Carlos Suarez Serrato and Owen Zidar, “Who Benefits from State Corporate Tax Cuts? A Local labor Markets Approach with Heterogeneous Firms,” American Economic Review, vol. 109, no. 9 (September 2016), pp. 2582-2624.

91The Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax on Wages: Evidence from Canadian Provinces Kenneth J. McKenzie and Ergete Ferede, April 2017, at http://econ.ucalgary.ca/manageprofile/sites/econ.ucalgary.ca.manageprofile/files/unitis/publications/1-7833135/UCWP_04_2017.pdf.

92N. Gregory Mankiw, “The Problem with the Corporate Tax,” New York Times, June 2, 2008.

93The lower share is due to valuation at the mean rather than the median. Most studies evaluate at the mean since the estimates reflect the mean values.

94Céline Azémar and Glenn Hubbard. “Country Characteristics and the Incidence of Capital Income Taxes on Wages: An Empirical Assessment, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 48, iss. 5 (December 2015), pp. 1762-1802.

95Gentry, William M. and R. Glenn Hubbard, “Distributional Implications of Introducing a Broad-Based Consumption Tax,” Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. 11 (1997), pp. 1-47.

96Jennifer Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence with Excess Profits, presented at the Proceedings of the National Tax Association Conference, 2015, at https://www.ntanet.org/wp-content/uploads/proceedings/2015/160-gravelle-corporate-tax-incidence-effect.pdf. A much earlier estimate of the excess profits on manufacturing seems consistent with a small magnitude, as the authors found a q value (stock market value relative to replacement value of capital) of 1.28, which implies a rent share of 22% (0.28/1.28). The authors suggest that this value is too high because the capital stock does not include intangible capital. See Lawrence F. Katz and Lawrence H. Summers, “Industry Rents: Evidence and Implications,” Brookings Papers: Microeconomics, 1989, pp. 209-290, at https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/1989/01/1989_bpeamicro_katz.pdf.

97See Megan Dunn and James Walker, Union Membership in the United States, Bureau of Labor Statistics, September 2016, https://www.bls.gov/spotlight/2016/union-membership-in-the-united-states/pdf/union-membership-in-the-united-states.pdf.

98Most studies found labor's share of to be less than 10%. See Andrew K. Hildreth and Andrew T. Oswald, “Rent — Sharing and Wages: Evidence from Country and Establishment Panels,” Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 15 (April 1997), pp. 318-337. Based on the means of the sample, their study of the UK indicated that labor's share of excess profit was about 5%. Four other articles, and a book, were cited as having similar results: Kevin Denny and Steve Machin, “The Role of Profitability and Industrial Wages in Firm-Level Wage Determination,” Fiscal Studies, May 1991, pp. 34-45; Louis Christofides and Andrew J. Oswald, “Real Wage Determination and Rent-sharing in Collective Bargaining Agreements,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 107 (August 1992), pp. 985-1002; David G. Blanchflower, Andrew J. Oswald and Peter Sanfey, 'Wages Profits and Rent-Sharing,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 111 (February 1996), pp. 227-251; and Alan A. Carruth and Andrew J. Oswald, Pay Determination and Industrial Prosperity (Oxford University Press: New York, 1989). These studies generally used U.K. data, although one used U.S. data and one used Canadian data. These studies were generally not economy wide but confined to sectors such as manufacturing. Two studies found, in one case, larger effects and in the other, mixed effects. John A. Abowd and Thomas Lemieux, “The Effects of Product market Competition on Collective Bargaining Agreements: The Case of Foreign Competition in Canada,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 198 (November 1993), pp. 983-1014 found a larger effect of 18% when they used instrumental variables to address endogeneity. John Van Reenen, “The Creation and Capture of Rents: Wages and Innovation in a Panel of U.K. Companies,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol.111 (February 1996), pp. 195-226, also using instruments, finds a share of about 5% when using quasi-rents (sales minus the alternative wage) but 35% when using profits. (Note: All of the shares presented in this note are derived by CRS and are calculated using the sample means.) These studies, of course, vary in quality and are subject to various critiques.

99This literature is summarized in R. Alison Felix and James R. Hines, Corporate Taxes and Union Wages in the United States, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper no. 15263, August 2009.

100Nadine Riedel, “Taxing Multi-Nationals Under Union Wage Bargaining,” International Tax and Public Finance, vol. 18 (August 2011), pp. 399-421 makes this point when she argues that increasing the domestic tax on a multinational with a surplus would actually, through this mechanism, cause domestic wages to rise and foreign wages to fall since the latter do not benefit from the higher value of deductibility.

101Wiji Arulampalam, Michael P. Devereux, and Giorgia Maffini, The Direct Incidence of Corporate Income Tax on Wages, Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation, March, 2011, published in the European Economic Review, vol. 56 (2012), pp. 1038-1054.

102Prior versions of this study reported larger results (in a 2008 version, that labor bears 96% of an increase in tax in the short run, and 92% in the long run, and in a 2007 version that labor bore 54% in the short run and 176% in the long run, at least for the specification that the authors reported.), which appear to reflect initially an increase in the sample and subsequently measuring incidence based on the mean rather than the median. These results seemed quite implausible.

103A number of proposed types of provisions, such as interest deduct ions, losses, and pension contribution would nevertheless be costs that are related to profits.

104This point is made by Jennifer C, Gravelle, Corporate Tax Incidence: A Review of Empirical Estimates and Analysis, CBO, Working Paper no. 2011-01, June 2011, http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/122xx/doc12239/06-14-2011-CorporateTaxIncidence.pdf. Note also that The regression is also run in logs that does not allow for negative tax liability even though the model is in levels.

105The tests used by the authors to determine their preferred specification are not without problems. See David Roodman, “How to Do xtabond2: An Introduction to “Difference” and “System” GMM in Stata,” Center for Global Development, Working Paper no. 103, December 2006.

106For example, no reason is presented for using a dynamic specification or the specific number of lagged variables, and the number of instruments was not reported.

107Nils aus dem Moore, Tanja Kasten, and Christoph M. Schmidt, “Do Wages Rise When Corporate Tax Rates Fall? Evidence from the German Business Tax Reform 2000,” January 11, 2011. An updated version of this working paper for 2014 found an even larger effect in the long run, see Ruhr Economic papers, no. 532, at https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/107692/1/819623113.pdf.

108Nadja Dwenger, Pia Rattenhuber, and Victor Steiner, “Sharing the Burden: Empirical Evidence on Corporate Tax Incidence,” Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Finance, 2011-14, October, 2011, http://www.tax.mpg.de/files/pdf1/ Dwenger-Rattenhuber-Steiner_Incidence_MPI.pdf.

109Thomas K. Bauer, Tanja Kasten, and Lars-H. R. Siemers, Business Taxation and Wages: Evidence from Individual Panel Data, Institute for the Study of Labor, Discussion Paper 6717, July 2012, at http://ftp.iza.org/dp6717.pdf.

110Clemens Fuest, Andreas Peichl, and Sebastian Siegloch, “ Do Higher Corporate Taxes Reduce Wages?” Micro Evidence from Germany, December 2016, at http://gabriel-zucman.eu/files/teaching/FuestEtal16.pdf, forthcoming, American Economic Review.

111Nils aus dem Moore, Shifting the Burden of Corporate Taxes: Heterogeneity in Direct Wage Incidence, Ruhr Economic Papers, no. 531, 2014, at https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/107694/1/819591319.pdf.

112Céline Azémar and R. Glenn Hubbard, “ Country Characteristics and the Incidence of Capital Income Taxation on Wages: An Empirical Assessment,” Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 48, iss. 5 (December 2015), pp. 1601-2004. The authors investigate an estimate that would capture both wage bargain ing and capital movement but found the estimate unreliable because of endogeneity issues, although the upper limit is large, a $2.65 decline in wages for each dollar of corporate revenue.

113This discussion indicates that the coefficient would fall from 0. 1 to 0.02 for countries with average labor union density such as France or Germany, implying an incidence of around 10%, and presumably would be less for the United States which had half the average union density over the period of study and has been declining since.

114Li Liu and Rosanne Altshuler, Measuring the Burden of a Corporate Tax Under Imperfect Competition, Oxford Working Paper no. 11/05, published in the National Tax Journal, vol. 66, no. 1 (March 2013), pp 215-238. This outcome occurs with unitary production and utility functions; when these functions are changed labor can bear a small amount of the burden, or labor can benefit from the tax with capital bearing slightly more than 100% of the burden. Labor can bear some nonnegligible share of the tax when factor substitution is much smaller in the corporate as compared to the noncorporate sector, but the reverse is likely to be the case since a large part of the noncorporate sector is housing services. See Jane G. Gravelle and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, “The Incidence and Efficiency Costs of Corporate Taxation When Corporate and Noncorporate Firms Produce the Same Goods, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 97, no. 4 (August 1979), pp. 749-780. This article has tables of incidence measures with different elasticities.

115One of the complications of estimating these tax rates is whether the estimates should consider the significant (over 50%) fraction of individual passive income that is held in tax exempt form through pensions, IRAs, life insurance annuities and nonprofits. In some ways, these sources can be viewed largely as not affecting marginal investment (for example, overall savings) because they are capped or not controlled directly by the investors and in other ways they affect choices (such as debt or equity of pension funds). The estimates in Table 9 use the share of stock held by U.S. individuals in taxable form, 25%. Setting the share at 50% would raise the tax rate on corporate equity from 6.2% to 9% under current law and from 13.8% to 15.3% under permanent law, and the overall effect on the corporate sector, total business, and economy wide taxes would be even smaller. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) uses a higher share of taxable stockholders and has some other assumptions that differ from the ones underlying these estimates. CBO, Taxing Capital Income: Effective Marginal Tax Rates Under 2014 Law and Selected Policy Options, December 2014, at https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/113th-congress-2013-2014/reports/49817-Taxing_Capital_Income_0.pdf. These measures are discussed in detail in CRS Report R44638, Corporate Tax Integration and Tax Reform, by Jane G. Gravelle.

116See Jane G. Gravelle, The Economic Effects of Taxing Capital Income (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1994), pp. 82-83, suggesting a distortion of about 0.17% of total consumption. With consumption (including government spending) about 83% of output, and the corporate tax 2.7%, this amounts to about 5% of corporate revenue. This amount has fallen slightly due to lower rates on capital gains and dividends. For estimates of the substitutability of debt and equity see Ruud de Mooij, The Tax Elasticity of Corporate Debt: A Synthesis of Size and Variations,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper WP/11/95, April 2011, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp1195.pdf.

117See the review in Gravelle, The Economic Effects of Taxing Capital Income, pp. 77-82.

118The distortion is proportional to the square of the wedge between pretax returns, which is tc/(1-tc)-t/(1-t), where tc is the corporate tax rate and the t the unincorporated. The corporate tax fell from about 44% in the mid-1980s to 32% today, while the noncorporate tax fell from 22% to 20% and the rate on owner occupied housing remained about the same (roughly zero). Holding the after-tax return constant, the wedge between corporate and noncorporate capital fell by over a half, and the square of the wedge by 80%. A calculation for owner-occupied housing suggests that the wedge fell by 40% and the deadweight loss by two-thirds. For the largest deadweight loss estimates, virtually all of the distortion was due to the corporate noncorporate differential, so that the current deadweight loss would be only 20% as large, while for the others, both assets played an important role.

119Estimates of 0.04% to 0.11% of consumption translate into 1% to 4% of corporate revenues, see Gravelle, The Economic Effects of Taxing Capital Income, p. 89. With the reduction in tax rat es of almost 50%, and the welfare cost proportional to the square of the tax wedge, the welfare cost would be about 30% of its former value or less than 1%. There is also a welfare cost from the realizations response of about 1%, but recent evidence has sh own this response to be small, about the same size as the pay-out distortion.

120See Jane G. Gravelle, “Income Consumption and Wage Taxation in a Life Cycle Model: Separating Efficiency from Redistribution,” American Economic Review, vol. 81, no. 4 (September 1991), pp. 985-995.

121See CRS Report R45186, Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L. 115-97), by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples for a more detailed discussion of int ernational tax issues.

122CRS Report R41743, International Corporate Tax Rate Comparisons and Policy Implications, by Jane G. Gravelle.

123Elke Asen, Corporate Tax Rates around the World, 2020, Tax Foundation, Fiscal Fact No. 735, December 2020, https://files.taxfoundation.org/20201208152358/2020-Corporate-Tax-Rates-around-the-World.pdf.

124Matthew Higgins, Tax Reform and U.S. Effective Profit Taxes: From Low to Lower, Liberty Street Economics, October 22, 2018, https://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2018/10/tax-reform-and-us-effective-profit-taxes-from-low-to-lower.html.

125See Kyle Pomerleau, who provides a composite equipment and structures measure weighted by capital stock. New York Fed Blog Post Understates Effective Corporate Tax Rates, Tax Foundation, October 26, 29018, https://taxfoundation.org/new-york-fed-blog-post-understates-effective-corporate-tax-rates/.

126The issues of efficiency in international taxation are discussed in much more detail in CRS Report RL34115, Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives, by Jane G. Gravelle.

127Jane G. Gravelle and Kent A. Smetters, “Does the Open Economy Assumption Really Mean That Labor Bears the Burden of a Capital Income Tax?” Advances in Economic Policy and Analysis, vol. 6, no. 1, 2006 find efficiency gains of 3% to 5% of revenue assuming the rest of the world had no tax and the United States had a 35% effective tax rate. Because tax rates are similar to those in the rest of the world, the efficiency effect is negligible and approaching zero.

128CBO, projections and historical data at https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#2. Note that in considering estimates, it is projections at the time the estimates were made that determine the magnitude.

129See CBO historical data, https://www.cbo.gov/data/budget-economic-data#2.

130CBO at https://www.cbo.gov/data/budget-economic-data#2.

131Department of the Treasury, “ General Explanations of the Administration's Fiscal Year 2022 Revenue Proposals,” May 2021, https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/tax-policy/revenue-proposals.

132See CRS Report R43568, Corporate Expatriation, Inversions, and Mergers: Tax Issues, by Donald J. Marples and Jane G. Gravelle for a discussion of inversions.

133This provision would expand the rules that prevent sales of related foreign corporation stock to U.S. firms from generating foreign tax credits to hybrid entities that are treated as a corporation in the foreign jurisdiction but as a partnership or disregarded entity (an entity not sees as a separate corporation) for U.S. tax purposes.

134Other provisions include repealing the credit for marginal wells, eliminating the exemption of oil and gas from the passive loss limits, eliminating the shorter term amortization of geological and geophysical costs, eliminating the expensing of mining exploration and development costs, eliminating percentage depletion for hard mineral fossil fuels, eliminating the capital gains treatment for royalties on coal, eliminating the exemption for fossil fuels from the rule treating publicly traded partnerships as corporations, and eliminating the shorter term amortization of pollution control facilities. Most of the fossil fuel changes are discussed in CRS Committee Print CP10004, Tax Expenditures: Compendium of Background Material on Individual Provisions — A Committee Print Prepared for the Senate Committee on the Budget, 2020, by Jane G. Gravelle et al.

135See CRS Report R40468, Tax Treaty Legislation in the 111th Congress: Explanation and Economic Analysis, by Donald J. Marples for a discussion of treaty shopping.

136See U.S. Congress, Senate Committee on Finance, International Tax Reform Framework Discussion Draft: Section-by-section description, at https://www.finance.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/section%20by%20section%20-%20WBW%20Framework%20discussion%20draft%208.20.21%20FINAL.pdf.

137Joint Committee on Taxation, Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2020, JCX-23-20, November 5, 2020, https://www.jct.gov/CMSPages/GetFile.aspx?guid=ec4fb616-771b-4708-8d16-f774d5158469.

138Estimates, originally made by the Joint Committee on Taxation, are reported in an out-of-print CRS report available on request, The Tax Reduction and Reform Act, by Jane G. Gravelle, RL34249, June 20, 2008.

139Senate Finance Committee, Baucus Works to Overhaul Outdated Tax Code, November 21, 2013, at http://www.finance.senate.gov/newsroom/chairman/release/?id=536eefeb-2ae2-453f-af9b-946c305d5c93.

140Senate Finance Committee, Baucus Unveils Proposals for International Tax Reform, November 19. 2013, at http://www.finance.senate.gov/newsroom/chairman/release/?id=f946a9f3-d296-42ad-bae4-bcf451b34b14.

141Check-the-box is a regulatory provision, but there is also a temporary prov ision that codifies and expands check-the-box. See CRS In Focus IF11392, H.R. 1865 and the Look-Through Treatment of Payments Between Related Controlled Foreign Corporations, by Jane G. Gravelle for additional explanation.

142See Joint Committee on Taxation, “ Estimated Revenue Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 2014, ” JCX-20-14, February 26, 2014, https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=4562 and “Technical Explanation of the Tax Reform Act of 2014,” Business Provisions, JCX-14-14, February 26, 2014, https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=4556, Participation Exemption System for the Taxation of Foreign.

143See Joint Committee on Taxation, “ Estimated Revenue Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 2014, ” JCX-20-14, February 26, 2014, https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=4562 and “Technical Explanation of the Tax Reform Act of 2014,” Business Provisions, JCX-14-14, February 26, 2014, https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=4556, Participation Exemption System for the Taxation of Foreign.

144See CRS Committee Print CP10004, Tax Expenditures: Compendium of Background Material on Individual Provisions — A Committee Print Prepared for the Senate Committee on the Budget, 2020, by Jane G. Gravelle et al.

145A number of individual provisions are discussed in CRS Report R41743, International Corporate Tax Rate Comparisons and Policy Implications, by Jane G. Gravelle, including accelerated depreciation, the production activities deduction, and the title passage rule inventory accounting. For a detailed discussion of corporate revenue raising provisions, see Jane G. Gravelle, “Raising Revenue From Reforming the Corporate Tax Base,” in John W. Diamond and George R. Zodrow., eds., Pathways to Fiscal Reform in the United States, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 2014.

146See CRS Report R45186, Issues in International Corporate Taxation: The 2017 Revision (P.L. 115-97), by Jane G. Gravelle and Donald J. Marples for a further discussion of the efficiency issues associated with the favorable treatment of foreign source income.

147The 2017 revision tightened a current rule restricting interest deductions, often referred to as the Section 163(j) limit, which had limited interest deductions to 50% of income before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization (EBITDA). This provision also had a safe harbor that exempted firms with debt-to-equity ratios of less than 1.5, which meant most firms even with large interest payments would not be affected. The 2017 change eliminated the safe harbor and lowered the limit to 30%. In 2022, in addition, the measure of income would become larger: income before taxes and interest (EBIT), which will make the provision more likely to apply to firms with large depreciation deductions, which are associated with equipment. Thus, there is already a provision limiting interest, which will shortly become more binding, but it is not associated with the share of nominal interest that reflects inflation.

148See CRS Report R41364, Capital Gains Tax Options: Behavioral Responses and Revenues, by Jane G. Gravelle for a review of the economic evidence.

149See CRS In Focus IF11812, Tax Treatment of Capital Gains at Death, by Jane G. Gravelle.

150See CRS Report R41364, Capital Gains Tax Options: Behavioral Responses and Revenues, by Jane G. Gravelle; and Jane G. Gravelle, “Sharing the Wealth: How to Tax the Rich,” National Tax Journal, vol. 73, no. 4, December 2020, pp. 951-968, for a discussion about revenue and design.

151Jane G. Gravelle and Kent A. Smetters, “Does the Open Economy Assumption Really Mean That Labor Bears the Burden of a Capital Income Tax?” Advances in Economic Policy and Analysis, vol. 6, no. 1, 2006.

152Thanks to the authors for providing their data. The studies are Kevin A. Hassett and Aparna Mathur, Taxes and Wages, American Enterprise Institute, working paper, 2006; and Kimberly A. Clausing, “Corporate Tax Revenues in OECD Countries,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 14 (2007), pp. 115-133.

153Alex Brill and Kevin A. Hassett, Revenue-Maximizing Corporate Income Taxes: The Laffer Curve in OECD Countries, American Enterprise Institute, Working Paper no.137, July 31, 2007.

154For ease of exposition only one independent variable is written in the equation. Generally, several independent variables are included in the linear model. This simplification does not change the following discussion of the model and estimation techniques.

155See Christopher F. Baum, An Introduction to Modern Econometrics Using Stata (College Station, TX: Stata Press, 2006) for a description of this technique. The overall results and conclusions are not changed when using the random effects estimation procedure allowing for an AR(1) error structure.

156Michael P. Devereux, Developments in the Taxation of Corporate Profit in the OECD Since 1965 : Rates, Bases and Revenues, University of Warwick, Working Paper, May 2006, p. 20.

END FOOTNOTES

DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
Copy RID