Menu
Tax Notes logo

CRS Updates Report on State and Local Taxes, Federal AMT

DEC. 28, 2006

RL32942

DATED DEC. 28, 2006
DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
  • Authors
    Maguire, Steven
  • Institutional Authors
    Congressional Research Service
  • Code Sections
  • Subject Area/Tax Topics
  • Jurisdictions
  • Language
    English
  • Tax Analysts Document Number
    Doc 2007-1621
  • Tax Analysts Electronic Citation
    2007 TNT 14-80
Citations: RL32942

 

Order Code RL32942

 

 

CRS Report for Congress

 

 

Updated December 28, 2006

 

 

Steven Maguire

 

Analyst in Public Finance

 

Government and Finance Division

 

 

State and Local Taxes and

 

the Federal Alternative Minimum Tax

 

 

Summary

The alternative minimum tax (AMT) is a parallel tax to the regular individual income tax and is intended to help ensure that high-income individuals bear at least some tax liability. The recent major tax cuts, however, lowered the average tax liability under the regular income tax such that many taxpayers could have been captured by the AMT, which is not indexed for inflation. The AMT for individuals will capture significantly more taxpayers beginning in the 2007 tax year if Congress does not act to modify or repeal the tax. This report describes the potential impact on taxpayers and state and local governments if the AMT reverts to pre-2001 rules or is repealed. Both taxpayers and state and local governments are potentially affected because state and local taxes are deducted for purposes of the regular income tax, but are not deducted when calculating AMT liability.

The impact on state and local governments arises because the tax price of public goods is reduced through federal deductibility. Each tax dollar a taxpayer (who itemizes) pays to a state or local government reduces the taxpayer's federal tax liability by an amount equal to his marginal tax rate multiplied by the taxes paid. Theoretically, state and local governments can levy higher taxes and provide more public goods than they would be able to absent federal deductibility. Through deductibility, state and local governments are also able to "export" part of their tax burden to all federal taxpayers, high-tax states more than others. Repeal of the AMT would expand the tax benefit generating more tax exportation. AMT reversion to pre-2001 rules would reduce the tax benefit and reduce tax exportation.

The variation of tax structures among states will lead to a significant differential impact by state and by individual. Generally, repeal of the AMT would reduce taxes for high-income taxpayers and reversion would increase taxes for high-income taxpayers. Most of the highest-income taxpayers (adjusted gross income over $500,000), however, would not be affected because their regular income tax liability exceeds AMT liability.

Generally, high-tax, high-income states would fare relatively better under AMT repeal and relatively worse under reversion to pre-2001 AMT rules. This report includes a state-by-state breakdown of the average taxes-paid deduction and the percentage of AMT filers and itemizers. This information is provided to help policymakers evaluate the effect of possible reforms of the AMT on constituent governments.

This report analyzes the broad impact of the AMT and options for its modification. For information on congressional action with respect to the AMT, see CRS Report RS22100, The Alternative Minimum Tax for Individuals: Legislative Initiatives and Their Revenue Effects, by Gregg A. Esenwein.

 Contents

 

 

 Effect of the AMT on Individuals

 

      Income Distribution of the State and Local Taxes Paid Deduction

 

      Income Distribution of AMT Liability

 

 

 Effect of the AMT on State and Local Governments

 

 

 Potential Issues for Congress

 

      AMT Reversion to Pre-2001 Rules

 

      Repeal of the AMT

 

 

 List of Tables

 

 

 Table 1. Returns by Income Class, Selected Characteristics, 2004

 

      Tax Year

 

 Table 2. Taxes Paid Deduction by Income Class, 2004 Tax Year

 

 Table 3. Income Distribution of Returns with AMT Liability, 2004

 

      Tax Year

 

 Table 4. AMT Filers and the Average Taxes Paid Deduction on Federal

 

      Income Tax Returns

 

State and Local Taxes and

 

the Federal Alternative Minimum Tax

 

 

The alternative minimum tax (AMT) is a parallel tax to the regular individual income tax and is intended to help ensure that high-income individuals bear at least some tax liability.1 The recent major tax cuts, however, lowered the average tax liability under the regular income tax such that many taxpayers could have been captured by the AMT, which is not indexed for inflation.

Congress temporarily adjusted the AMT exemption amounts in 2001 (through the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act, EGTRRA) and 2003 (through the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act, JGTRRA). Congress extended the temporary exemption amount increases in 2004 (through the Working Families Tax Relief Act, WFTRA) and again in 2006 (the Tax Increase Prevention and Reconciliation Act of 2005, TIPRA).2 By increasing the AMT exemption amount, the threshold where regular income tax liability falls below AMT liability is relatively higher, temporarily reducing the number of taxpayers subject to the AMT. In addition, some personal credits that were previously not allowed to offset AMT liability can now be used to offset the AMT.

Potential changes to the AMT would have a significant effect on the taxes levied on individuals and on the tax structure of state and local governments. Specifically, the distribution of the federal tax burden on individuals would change if either extreme, reversion to pre-2001 rules or repeal of the AMT, is implemented. State and local governments would either see the tax price for public goods increase (reversion) or decrease (repeal).

The report includes a state-by-state breakdown of the average "taxes paid deduction" and the percentage of AMT filers and itemizers. This information is provided to help policymakers evaluate the effect of possible reforms on constituent governments. The report concludes with a discussion of how congressional action on the AMT could affect state and local governments and taxpayers if Congress takes action dealing with the AMT before 2007.

 

Effect of the AMT on Individuals

 

 

The potential distributional effects of AMT reform or repeal on individuals is the focus of this section. There are two primary avenues through which the tax burden would be shifted: through the treatment of state and local taxes paid and through the distributional burden of the AMT generally. A secondary effect would arise as states and individuals respond to any new treatment of state and local taxes under the AMT or without an AMT. How the burden is currently distributed will help frame how burden would change under proposals to repeal or reform the AMT. Table 1 provides a distribution of taxpayers based on the utilization of itemized deductions, the taxes paid deduction, and the presence of AMT tax liability for all returns.

          Table 1. Returns by Income Class, Selected Characteristics,

 

                                 2004 Tax Year

 

 

                                            Returns      Returns       Returns

 

                              Returns        with       with Taxes      with

 

 Adjusted Gross              in Income     Itemized       Paid          AMT

 

  Income Class                 Class      Deductions    Deduction     Liability

 

 

 less than $5,000           13,525,330       327,379      308,704         4,762

 

 $5,001 to $10,000          12,135,417       642,831      604,809            35

 

 $10,000 to $15,000         11,656,193     1,078,646    1,041,981         3,082

 

 $15,000 to $20,000         11,281,291     1,408,086    1,365,983         1,672

 

 $20,000 to $25,000          9,705,192     1,591,869    1,569,755           972

 

 $25,000 to $30,000          8,512,113     1,897,697    1,870,482         1,339

 

 $30,000 to $40,000         13,915,452     4,539,560    4,489,693         1,664

 

 $40,000 to $50,000         10,571,408     4,654,789    4,626,511        11,818

 

 $50,000 to $75,000         18,047,126    10,658,268   10,612,957        89,396

 

 $75,000 to $100,000        10,119,515     7,926,317    7,917,281       155,065

 

 $100,000 to $200,000        9,735,569     8,776,391    8,771,965     1,095,242

 

 $200,000 to $500,000        2,348,163     2,215,675    2,212,464     1,529,159

 

 $500,000 to $1,000,000        433,145       398,317      397,824       149,042

 

 $1,000,000 to $1,500,000      103,964        93,599       93,307        24,574

 

 $1,500,000 to $2,000,000       45,104        40,698       40,637         9,720

 

 $2,000,000 to $5,000,000       65,548        60,674       60,545        13,423

 

 $5,000,000 to $10,000,000      15,835        15,036       15,005         3,258

 

 $10,000,000 and over            9,677         9,404        9,388         2,077

 

 All Returns               132,226,042    46,335,237   46,009,291     3,096,299

 

 

 Source: IRS, Statistics of Income, Individual Complete Report 2004,

 

 Publication 1304, September 2006.

 

 

Generally, as adjusted gross income increases, so to does the prevalence of returns with itemized deductions, a taxes paid deduction, and AMT liability. Note that the vast majority of taxpayers with AGI greater than $75,000, itemize and claim a deduction for state and local taxes paid.

Income Distribution of the State and Local Taxes Paid Deduction

Under the regular income tax, individuals who itemize deductions may deduct state and local taxes paid. Taxpayers must choose to deduct either income or sales taxes, not both.3 In the 2003 tax year, before the sales tax deduction option was available, 43.1 million returns deducted $310.9 billion in taxes paid.4 In the 2004 tax year, the first year for the sales tax deduction option, 46.0 million returns deducted $362.6 billion.5 The increase in number of returns claiming the taxes paid deduction, 6.8%, and in the amount deducted, 16.6%, is likely due in large part to the sales tax deduction option. In contrast to the regular income tax treatment, under the alternative minimum tax (AMT) state and local taxes paid are considered a preference item and are included in the base of the tax. According to one estimate, approximately 2 million taxpayers "added back" approximately $42 billion in state and local taxes paid for purposes of calculating AMT tax liability.6

The taxes paid deduction is most common for returns in the higher income brackets. Out of the 22.9 million total returns with reported AGI of over $75,000, 19.5 million itemized deductions (see Table 1). The over $75,000 cohort of itemizing taxpayers represented 42.2% of itemized returns yet claimed 71.1% of the total taxes paid deduction (see Table 2). Those with AGI greater than $100,000 represented 9.6% of all returns yet accounted for 56.3% of the state and local taxes paid deduction.

As is often the case with federal tax policy, different parts of the tax code contradict one another. The treatment of state and local taxes is one example. The policy objective behind the tax preference for state and local taxes paid under the regular income tax has been supported with the claim that to disallow the deduction would amount to a "tax on a tax."7 Proponents of the deduction suggest that taxes paid to state and local governments are not available to pay federal income taxes and thus should not be included in taxable income. In short, proponents of deductibility claim that "taxing a tax" is inequitable. If the AMT were to revert to the pre-2001 rules, this tax preference would be reduced, contravening the original intent of the tax deduction under the regular income tax.

          Table 2. Taxes Paid Deduction by Income Class, 2004 Tax Year

 

 

                                                      Percentage   Percentage

 

                              Returns    Amount of     of Taxes     of Taxes

 

                             with Taxes  Taxes Paid      Paid        Paid

 

 Adjusted Gross                Paid      Deduction    Deduction     Deduction

 

 Income Class                Deduction   (in $ 000s)   Returns      Amount

 

 

 less than $5,000              308,704      842,420      0.7%         0.2%

 

 $5,001 to $10,000             604,809    1,575,481      1.3%         0.4%

 

 $10,000 to $15,000          1,041,981    2,654,681      2.3%         0.7%

 

 $15,000 to $20,000          1,365,983    3,763,526      3.0%         1.0%

 

 $20,000 to $25,000          1,569,755    4,301,689      3.4%         1.2%

 

 $25,000 to $30,000          1,870,482    5,256,638      4.1%         1.5%

 

 $30,000 to $40,000          4,489,693   14,486,137      9.8%         4.0%

 

 $40,000 to $50,000          4,626,511   17,888,345     10.1%         4.9%

 

 $50,000 to $75,000         10,612,957   53,852,396     23.1%        14.9%

 

 $75,000 to $100,000         7,917,281   53,668,295     17.2%        14.8%

 

 $100,000 to $200,000        8,771,965   90,863,750     19.1%        25.1%

 

 $200,000 to $500,000        2,212,464   49,391,413      4.8%        13.6%

 

 $500,000 to $1,000,000        397,824   19,872,214      0.9%         5.5%

 

 $1,000,000 to $1,500,000       93,307    8,073,240      0.2%         2.2%

 

 $1,500,000 to $2,000,000       40,637    4,894,309      0.1%         1.4%

 

 $2,000,000 to $5,000,000       60,545   11,858,211      0.1%         3.3%

 

 $5,000,000 to $10,000,000      15,005    6,272,759      0.0%         1.7%

 

 $10,000,000 and over            9,388   13,093,348      0.0%         3.6%

 

 All Returns                46,009,291  362,608,853    100.0%       100.0%

 

 

 Source: IRS, Statistics of Income, Individual Complete Report

 

 2004, Publication 1304, September 2006.

 

 

In contrast, if the taxes paid to state and local governments are viewed as payments for services (e.g., education services and garbage collection) some assert that a deduction for these taxes would not be justified. Reversion to pre-2001 AMT rules would be more consistent with this view. The characteristics of the goods and services provided by jurisdictions, in this view, determine the theoretical appropriateness of the deduction for the taxes used to pay for them. For example, consider jurisdiction "A" that provides foreign language classes and a government operated fitness center and jurisdiction "B" which does not offer either. If A funds these services with local property taxes, taxpayers (who itemize) are allowed to deduct the cost of these services through the federal deduction for state and local taxes paid. In contrast, taxpayers in jurisdiction B who purchase similar services, albeit from private providers, cannot deduct the expenditure. From a distributional perspective, jurisdictions that provide more services (jurisdiction "A" in our example) -- likely wealthier jurisdictions -- are able to export some of the burden to all federal taxpayers, including to those in poorer jurisdictions. Generally, the greater the likelihood of a private provider of a good or service, the less appropriate, some argue, is the federal deduction for the taxes used to fund those services.

The previous discussion touches on another justification for the deduction for state and local taxes: the indirect subsidy to state and local governments. The lower "tax price," theoretically, allows the local government to impose a tax rate that is higher than would be the case without deductibility.8 For example, if a taxpayer is allowed to deduct property taxes, it is likely the case that these taxpayers would be more willing to accept a marginally higher property tax rate. For each dollar of property tax paid, the federal tax burden is reduced by the taxpayers marginal tax rate. A taxpayer in the 28% tax bracket would have federal tax liability reduced by 28 cents for each dollar paid in property taxes.

Economic theory predicts that more public services would be provided than would otherwise be the case without deductibility. The taxpayer has more disposable income (lower federal taxes), and thus would demand more public services. And, the relative price of government provided goods would decline, increasing the quantity of public goods demanded.9

From a state distributional perspective, high-tax, high-income states would benefit the most under expanded deductibility of state and local taxes (e.g., AMT repeal). This report provides a more detailed discussion of the effect on state and local governments of the taxes paid deduction under AMT reform (and repeal) proposals in a later section.

Income Distribution of AMT Liability

The AMT affects considerably fewer taxpayers than the itemized deduction for taxes paid; 3.1 million and 46.3 million in 2004). The distribution of those affected by the AMT, however, is more concentrated than is the taxes paid deduction. The aggregated data produced by the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) and summarized in Table 3 clearly exhibit the concentrated (and progressive) nature of AMT liability; 84.8% of AMT returns reported AGI between $100,000 and $500,000.

CBO testimony from May 2005 indicates that the share of taxpayers with AGI greater than $500,000 subject to the AMT would not change significantly if the AMT reverts to pre-2001 rules (see Table 3). In contrast, the share of taxpayers subject to the AMT in the $50,000 to $100,000 cohort and the $100,000 to $200,000 cohort would rise dramatically.10 For these cohorts, the AMT rates are higher than the regular income tax rates. Taxpayers in the over $500,000 cohort encounter higher tax rates under the regular income tax than under the AMT and thus would not be affected by AMT reversion to pre-2001 rules.

          Table 3. Income Distribution of Returns with AMT Liability,

 

                                 2004 Tax Year

 

 

                                         Amount of

 

                             Returns       AMT       Percentage  Percentage

 

 Adjusted Gross              with AMT    Liability     of AMT     of AMT

 

  Income Class               Liability  (in $ 000s)   Returns    Liability

 

 

 less than $5,000               4,762      $88,815      0.2%        0.7%

 

 $5,001 to $10,000                 35          612      0.0%        0.0%

 

 $10,000 to $15,000             3,082        1,782      0.1%        0.0%

 

 $15,000 to $20,000             1,672        3,386      0.1%        0.0%

 

 $20,000 to $25,000               972        1,537      0.0%        0.0%

 

 $25,000 to $30,000             1,339        1,171      0.0%        0.0%

 

 $30,000 to $40,000             1,664          448      0.1%        0.0%

 

 $40,000 to $50,000            11,818       19,019      0.4%        0.1%

 

 $50,000 to $75,000            89,396      116,192      2.9%        0.9%

 

 $75,000 to $100,000          155,065      224,349      5.0%        1.7%

 

 $100,000 to $200,000       1,095,242    2,058,479     35.4%       15.8%

 

 $200,000 to $500,000       1,529,159    6,831,014     49.4%       52.4%

 

 $500,000 to $1,000,000       149,042    1,645,295      4.8%       12.6%

 

 $1,000,000 to $1,500,000      24,574      452,148      0.8%        3.5%

 

 $1,500,000 to $2,000,000       9,720      257,229      0.3%        2.0%

 

 $2,000,000 to $5,000,000      13,423      538,675      0.4%        4.1%

 

 $5,000,000 to $10,000,000      3,258      269,065      0.1%        2.1%

 

 $10,000,000 and over           2,077      520,024      0.1%        4.0%

 

 All Returns                3,096,299   13,029,239    100.0%      100.0%

 

 

 Source: IRS, Statistics of Income, Individual Complete Report 2004,

 

 Publication 1304, September 2006.

 

 

Estimates of the anticipated AMT liability distribution if the current laws governing the AMT are not changed is a principal concern of many observers and policymakers. According to analysis from the Urban Institute -- Brookings Tax Policy Center, under current law, taxpayers with AGI under $200,000 will pay almost 46% of AMT liability in 2010, compared to less than 9% that the group paid in 2006.11 In addition, the same analysis estimates that the number of AMT taxpayers will increase to 32.4 million in 2010 from 3.5 million in 2006. Although the AMT would still be relatively progressive in 2010, the increased burden on less wealthy taxpayers and the greater absolute number of taxpayers subject to the AMT, would diminish the overall progressivity of the federal tax system.

 

Effect of the AMT on State and Local Governments

 

 

This section describes and analyzes how possible congressional action on the AMT may affect state and local governments. Generally, under the AMT, state and local taxes paid do not receive a federal tax preference. In contrast, the repeal of the AMT combined with the scheduled repeal of the regular income itemized deduction phase-out would significantly increase the tax benefit conferred on states through deductibility.12 For these reasons, state and local governments are actively following congressional action on the AMT.

State and local government representatives generally support the deductibility of state and local taxes under the regular income tax because of the indirect subsidy to sub-national governments delivered through a lower federal tax burden. Generally, state and local governments are able to "export" part of their tax burden to all federal taxpayers -- some states more than others. Exporting the state and local tax burden can be measured by the amount of tax revenue that is deductible. The greater the amount of deductible taxes, the greater the exportation.

Recent tax cut legislation, the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 (AJCA 2004), expanded the deductibility of the state and local taxes to include an option to deduct sales taxes in lieu of income taxes for taxpayers that itemize.13 Taxpayers choose the greater of sales taxes or income taxes when itemizing deductions. The new provision primarily benefits taxpayers in states that do not levy an income tax. The provision expires after 2007.

A variety of methods can be used to compare the relative tax burden of state and local taxes. For this report, state and local taxes that could have been deductible under AJCA 2004 rules were chosen as the instrument of comparison. The greater of sales taxes or income taxes was added to property taxes for each state. This amount was then divided by the number of 2004 tax returns filed in each state to produce an average amount for each state. The third column of Table 4 presents these estimates of the average "deductible" taxes per return, by state. Note that because businesses pay a large portion of sales and property taxes, the averages overstate the burden on individual returns, yet the estimates are useful for comparative purposes.

Potentially deductible taxes (under the AJCA rules) would have been $7,313, on average, for returns filed in New York state; $2,551 in Alabama (see Table 4). The U.S. average was $4,588 per return.14 Recall that state and local governments that rely more on deductible taxes pay a relatively lower "tax price" for public goods. Jurisdictions in New York state, for example, pay a lower tax price and export more of their tax burden to federal taxpayers than do jurisdictions in Alabama.

Table 4 also presents data on the percentage of AMT filers by state and the average state and local taxes paid deduction by state in FY2002. Note that taxpayers in states that do not levy an income tax will have a greater incentive to itemize and claim the deduction for taxes paid.15 The average taxes paid deduction will almost certainly rise in these states as existing itemizers simply add the sales tax paid to other itemized deductions. The IRS reported that in 2004 "[A]n estimated 11.1 million taxpayers took advantage of this [sales tax deduction], deducting $17.3 billion."16 There are likely many taxpayers in these states who did not itemize before AJCA was enacted, but were relatively close to the threshold where itemized deductions could exceed the standard deduction.

According to the tables in IRS Publication 600, the state sales tax deduction for a family of four in Knoxville, Tennessee, with income between $100,000 and $120,000, would have been $1,496 in 2004 ($1,682 in 2006).17 In addition, this family could deduct another $481 ($541 in 2006) for local sales taxes paid. Further, if this family had purchased a $20,000 car (or boat), they could deduct another $1,850. In sum, this Tennessee family could have deducted an additional $3,827 under the sales tax deduction option. With the standard deduction for joint filers at $9,700 in 2004, it seems reasonable to assume that the additional sales tax deduction would have induced itemizing for many taxpayers in a similar situation.

The data from the U.S. Census Bureau in the third column of Table 4 include the property tax and either the sales tax or income tax. The tax which generates the most revenue, either income or sales, was added to the property tax to simulate a state's reliance on deductible taxes. Comparing states based on what current law would allow seems to be a reasonable proposition.

States without a broad based state income tax are indicated by an asterisk. Note that unlike other states, almost all these states have an average amount of potentially deductible taxes that is greater than the average actual taxes paid deduction.

          Table 4. AMT Filers and the Average Taxes Paid Deduction on

 

                           Federal Income Tax Returns

 

 

                                   Total

 

                        AMT       Property,   Percentage     Average State

 

     State           Filers as    Income or   of Filers      and Local Taxes

 

 (* indicates no     Percentage  Sales Taxes  Itemizing      Paid Deduction

 

  broad-based          of all    per Return   Deductions

 

  state income        Returns      Filed        2004          2003      2004

 

     tax)              2004        2004

 

 

 U.S. Average            2.36%      $4,588       34.96%     $5,874    $8,032

 

 Alabama                 0.74%      $2,551       29.90%     $3,624    $4,208

 

 Alaska*                 0.69%      $2,919       24.63%     $2,864    $3,486

 

 Arizona                 1.30%      $4,739       37.97%     $4,816    $5,392

 

 Arkansas                1.09%      $3,462       24.21%     $4,883    $5,914

 

 California              3.96%      $4,626       39.59%     $8,884   $10,652

 

 Colorado                1.52%      $4,211       42.13%     $5,293    $5,732

 

 Connecticut             4.82%      $6,679       44.27%    $10,424   $12,201

 

 Delaware                1.63%      $3,238       36.40%     $5,492    $6,257

 

 D.C.                    4.23%      $7,476       42.33%     $9,234   $10,404

 

 Florida*                1.45%      $4,465       31.57%     $3,707    $5,280

 

 Georgia                 1.93%      $3,951       39.00%     $5,960    $7,100

 

 Hawaii                  1.61%      $4,324       33.27%     $5,299    $6,038

 

 Idaho                   1.39%      $3,570       34.89%     $5,135    $5,859

 

 Illinois                1.95%      $4,475       36.20%     $6,475    $7,420

 

 Indiana                 1.02%      $3,795       30.22%     $5,192    $5,919

 

 Iowa                    1.28%      $3,915       31.58%     $5,717    $6,402

 

 Kansas                  1.56%      $4,660       30.75%     $6,230    $6,922

 

 Kentucky                1.36%      $3,280       30.53%     $6,028    $6,759

 

 Louisiana               0.97%      $4,062       21.46%     $3,523    $5,722

 

 Maine                   1.88%      $5,267       30.88%     $7,301    $8,266

 

 Maryland                3.90%      $5,428       49.45%     $7,944    $8,894

 

 Massachusetts           3.79%      $6,091       41.05%     $8,655    $9,828

 

 Michigan                1.52%      $4,357       36.72%     $6,099    $6,621

 

 Minnesota               2.39%      $4,415       41.66%     $6,804    $7,643

 

 Mississippi             0.67%      $3,725       22.94%     $3,966    $6,859

 

 Missouri                1.34%      $3,463       31.02%     $5,768    $6,433

 

 Montana                 1.38%      $3,558       30.48%     $5,296    $6,020

 

 Nebraska                1.64%      $4,658       30.45%     $6,591    $7,291

 

 Nevada*                 1.24%      $4,224       37.04%     $2,904    $4,535

 

 New Hampshire*          1.74%      $4,003       35.63%     $6,126    $6,945

 

 New Jersey              5.55%      $6,240       44.89%    $10,003   $11,419

 

 New Mexico              1.06%      $3,379       26.73%     $5,076    $5,310

 

 New York                5.07%      $7,313       38.58%    $11,098   $13,316

 

 North Carolina          1.85%      $3,609       36.03%     $6,252    $6,921

 

 North Dakota            0.77%      $3,329       18.40%     $4,471    $5,311

 

 Ohio                    2.21%      $4,299       34.09%     $6,721    $7,522

 

 Oklahoma                1.08%      $2,994       29.49%     $5,133    $7,968

 

 Oregon                  2.31%      $4,881       41.50%     $7,222    $8,015

 

 Pennsylvania            1.97%      $3,928       31.75%     $6,548    $7,591

 

 Rhode Island            2.69%      $5,315       37.50%     $8,259    $9,322

 

 South Carolina          1.41%      $3,550       32.44%     $5,629    $6,188

 

 South Dakota*           0.59%      $4,120       18.40%     $2,778    $3,788

 

 Tennessee*              0.68%      $4,091       25.21%     $2,161    $3,895

 

 Texas*                  1.25%      $5,018       25.33%     $4,288    $6,270

 

 Utah                    1.38%      $3,676       40.14%     $5,089    $6,145

 

 Vermont                 1.92%      $4,507       29.88%     $6,926    $7,803

 

 Virginia                2.55%      $4,336       40.42%     $6,666    $7,662

 

 Washington*             1.23%      $5,654       36.74%     $3,262    $5,639

 

 West Virginia           0.82%      $2,738       17.46%     $5,325    $5,947

 

 Wisconsin               1.98%      $4,838       38.10%     $7,692    $8,435

 

 Wyoming*                0.86%      $5,291       21.77%     $2,761    $3,944

 

 

 Source: Internal Revenue Service, Census of Governments 2003-2004, and

 

 CRS calculations.

 

Potential Issues for Congress

 

 

Congress might ultimately choose one of three basic approaches to address the AMT. The first is to allow the AMT to revert to the pre-2001 rules. If no further action is taken on the AMT in 2006, the reversion would occur beginning with the 2007 tax year. The second approach is continued modification of the AMT to capture roughly the same number of taxpayers every year. This would require annual adjustment of the higher AMT exemption amounts through indexation or a similar process. Thirdly, the AMT could be repealed outright.

If the AMT is repealed, federal revenue will decline considerably as current budget forecasts predict repeal would generate a $611 billion revenue loss over the 2006-2015 budget window, assuming the EGTRRA and JGTRRA tax cuts are not extended.18 If the other regular income tax cuts are extended and the AMT is repealed, the federal revenue loss over the same budget window would be approximately $1.16 trillion.19

The second option, extension of the highest AMT exemption and indexation, would essentially maintain the status quo and would not significantly shift the burden of federal taxation among the states. But, because current law does not index the AMT, the cost of indexation under this option (beginning with the higher AMT exemption amounts) would be $385 billion over the 2006-2015 budget window assuming the regular income tax cuts are not extended.20 If the tax cuts are extended, the cost of this proposal would rise to $642 billion.21 In contrast to indexation, the two extremes, reversion and repeal, would likely have significant impact on state and local governments and would significantly alter the burden of federal taxation. For a discussion of the revenue cost of various reform options for the AMT, see CRS Report RS22100, The Alternative Minimum Tax: Legislative Initiatives and Their Revenue Effects, by Gregg A. Esenwein.

AMT Reversion to Pre-2001 Rules

If the AMT is allowed to revert to the structure in place before 2001, and the regular income tax cuts (EGTRRA and JGTRRA) are made permanent, then the role of state and local taxes in determining federal tax liability will change significantly. Under this scenario, the AMT would capture many more taxpayers as regular income tax liability falls below the floor established by the AMT. State and local taxes paid, as noted earlier, would become taxable, reducing the implicit federal transfer to state and local governments. Because the deduction for state and local taxes paid varies by state, so too will the impact of AMT adjustments.

For example, the average taxes paid itemized deduction for filers residing in New York was $13,316 in 2004 whereas in Tennessee, the average taxes paid itemized deduction was $3,895 (see Table 4). The reason for the disparity arises from the following two factors: the level of state and local taxes and the average income in the state. Generally, higher state and local taxes and higher income would both contribute to a higher likelihood of itemizing and claiming a deduction for state and local taxes paid.

States with the highest average amount of state and local taxes deducted (New York, Connecticut, New Jersey, California, District of Columbia, Massachusetts, and Rhode Island are the top seven) would be the most negatively affected if the AMT is allowed to revert to pre-2001 rules. In contrast, states with relatively low taxes paid deductions, (Alaska, South Dakota, Tennessee, Wyoming, Alabama, Nevada, and Florida) would be the least negatively affected. Note that six of the seven states with the relatively small taxes paid deduction are states without broad-based income taxes. If the AJCA 2004 sales tax deduction option were extended beyond 2007, reversion to pre-2001 AMT rules would have a greater negative impact on these states. The burden of federal taxes would shift from the low tax states to the high tax states if the AMT reverts unchanged to pre-2001 rules. Note that reversion to pre-2001 rules would result in a significant increase in the number of AMT filers in all states, regardless of state and local taxes.

Repeal of the AMT

In contrast to allowing the AMT to revert to pre-2001 rules, Congress could repeal the AMT and state and local governments would continue to receive an indirect benefit through deductibility of state and local taxes. The elimination of the phase-out of itemized deductions under the regular income tax in 2009 would also enhance the taxpayer benefit derived from deducting state and local taxes.

If the AMT is repealed, the loss in revenue would necessarily result in one or more of the following: greater federal debt, an increase in other federal taxes, and/or reduced federal spending. If federal debt is increased, the cost of borrowing for both the government and the private sector, will also increase. State and local governments, which typically rely on debt to fund public infrastructure, such as schools, roads, and bridges, would likely face higher interest costs as the supply of all types of government bonds expands. The long-run drag on the economy generated by government dissaving, however, could be partially offset by the short-term stimulative effect of lower taxes.

The impact of increasing other federal taxes to replace the lost AMT revenue depends on the tax raised and how the tax is increased. If the base of the regular federal income tax (personal or corporate) is expanded (e.g., the elimination of special deductions or exclusions), many states could receive a slight windfall. A windfall arises because most states use the base of the federal income tax (both individual and corporate) as the starting point for state income taxes. For this reason, if state and local tax rates remain constant, the expanded federal base would increase state and local tax revenue. Alternatively, an increase in federal rates or the elimination of lower tax brackets would have little effect on most state income tax revenue. Other federal tax changes, such as changes in excise taxes, would likely have little direct effect on the state and local government finances.

Spending cuts would likely include some reduction in grants-in-aid to state and local governments. These grants comprised approximately 14% ($357.8 billion) of total federal government current expenditures in 2005.22 In addition, cuts in federal spending, other than direct grants, may also adversely affect states if states must increase spending to provide what was once provided by the federal government.

Many observers agree that the AMT issue will need to be addressed again in the next Congress. In addition, proposals addressing fundamental tax reform could include reform of the AMT. The direction of any congressional choice would have a significant and varied impact on taxpayers and on state and local governments.

 

FOOTNOTES

 

 

1 For more on the AMT, see CRS Report RL30149, The Alternative Minimum Tax for Individuals, by Gregg Esenwein.

2 The WFTRA AMT extension is through the 2005 tax year. The TIPRA extension is through the 2006 tax year.

3 Under current law, the option to deduct sales taxes in lieu of income tax expires at the end of 2007.

4 IRS, Statistics of Income, Individual Complete Report 2003, Publication 1304, Oct. 2005. The sales tax deduction option was not available in 2003; it became available for the 2004 tax year.

5 IRS, Statistics of Income, Individual Complete Report 2004, Publication 1304, Sept. 2006.

6 U.S. Department of Treasury, Office of Tax Analysis, unpublished data as cited by: Len Berman and David Weiner, "Suppose We Took the AM Out of the Alternative Minimum Tax," paper presented at the National Tax Association, 97th Annual Conference on Taxation, Nov. 11-13, 2004.

7 See CRS Report RL32781, Federal Deductibility of State and Local Taxes, by Steven Maguire.

8 Douglas Holtz-Eakin and Harvey Rosen, "Federal Deductibility and Local Property Tax Rates," Journal of Urban Economics, vol. 27, 1990, pp. 269-284.

9 Economists refer to these effects as the income and substitution effects, respectively.

10 Douglas Holtz-Eakin, Congressional Budget Office Testimony, "The Individual Alternative Minimum Tax," before the Subcommittee on Taxation and IRS Oversight, Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate, May 23, 2005, figure 4, p. 6.

11 Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, Table T06-0270, Washington D.C., Nov. 10, 2006.

12 Under current law, through 2009, certain high-income taxpayers are required to reduce itemized deductions (limited to up to 80% of allowable deductions). This itemized deduction reduction is phased out beginning in the 2006 tax year until completely repealed beginning in 2009.

13 For more, see CRS Report RL32781, Federal Deductibility of State and Local Taxes, by Steven Maguire.

14 Note that these estimates are considerably less than the standard deduction in 2002, $7,850 for married taxpayers and $4,700 for single taxpayers. This explains in part the relatively small number of taxpayers that itemize.

15 See CRS Report RL32781, Federal Deductibility of State and Local Taxes, by Steven Maguire.

16 Balkovic, 2006, p. 10.

17 The state sales tax rate in Tennessee is 7%, and the local rate for Knoxville is an additional 2.25% for a combined sales tax rate of 9.25%.

18 Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, Congressional Budget Office Testimony, "The Individual Alternative Minimum Tax," before the Subcommittee on Taxation and IRS Oversight, Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate, May 23, 2005, p. 8.

19 U.S. Department of Treasury, Fact Sheet: A Tale of Two Taxes, Regular Income Tax and the AMT, March 2, 2005.

20 Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, Congressional Budget Office Testimony, "The Individual Alternative Minimum Tax," before the Subcommittee on Taxation and IRS Oversight, Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate, May 23, 2005, Table 1, p. 8.

21 Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2006 to 2015, January 2005, p. 8.

22Economic Report of the President, Feb. 2006, Table B-82, p. 379.

 

END OF FOOTNOTES
DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
  • Authors
    Maguire, Steven
  • Institutional Authors
    Congressional Research Service
  • Code Sections
  • Subject Area/Tax Topics
  • Jurisdictions
  • Language
    English
  • Tax Analysts Document Number
    Doc 2007-1621
  • Tax Analysts Electronic Citation
    2007 TNT 14-80
Copy RID