Menu
Tax Notes logo

Brattle Group Report Analyzes Impact of Reinsurance Bill

JUL. 8, 2010

Brattle Group Report Analyzes Impact of Reinsurance Bill

DATED JUL. 8, 2010
DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
  • Authors
    Cragg, Michael
    Cummins, J. David
    Zhou, Bin
  • Institutional Authors
    Brattle Group Inc.
  • Cross-Reference
    For H.R. 3424, see Doc 2009-18189 or 2009 TNT 154-28 2009 TNT 154-28: Proposed Legislation.
  • Code Sections
  • Subject Area/Tax Topics
  • Jurisdictions
  • Language
    English
  • Tax Analysts Document Number
    Doc 2010-15377
  • Tax Analysts Electronic Citation
    2010 TNT 133-24
  • Magazine Citation
    The Insurance Tax Review, Aug. 1, 2010, p. 423
    39 Ins. Tax Rev. 423 (Aug. 1, 2010)
The Impact on the U.S. Insurance Market of H.R. 3424 on Offshore Affiliate Reinsurance: An Updated Economic Analysis

 

July 8, 2010

 

 

Michael Cragg, The Brattle Group

 

 

J. David Cummins, Fox School of Business, Temple University

 

and The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

 

 

Bin Zhou, The Brattle Group

 

 

_____________________________________________________________________

 

Prepared on behalf of

 

 

The Coalition for Competitive Insurance Rates, with support from the Association of Bermuda Insurers and Reinsurers (ABIR) and Leading European Reinsurers and Insurers
_____________________________________________________________________

 

 

SUMMARY

 

 

Congress is considering H.R. 3424, legislation that would impose a significant tax on reinsurance that a foreign-owned U.S. insurance firm buys from an offshore affiliate. The legislation is a response to pressure from some U.S.-owned insurance groups that portray offshore affiliate reinsurance as a tax-avoidance strategy. These groups argue that the tax is necessary to level the playing field and will not harm U.S. consumers. A coalition of insurance firms opposed to the legislation asked us to evaluate the economic impact of the tax. We summarize our conclusions below.

Reinsurance is critical to risk management in the property and casualty (P&C) insurance industry, particularly for natural catastrophes and other infrequent but high-loss events.

  • Much of the global demand for reinsurance comes from the United States, which has the world's largest insurance market and faces unique risks from natural disasters and the U.S. legal liability system. United States accounted for 76 percent of worldwide insured losses for natural catastrophes between 2000 and 2009.

  • The key function of reinsurance is risk-pooling and diversification. An insurer can reduce the volatility of its losses by ceding its exposure to particular risks. A reinsurer can bear these risks more efficiently because it assumes them from a variety of sources and many of the risks (e.g., hurricanes in Florida and earthquakes in Japan) are uncorrelated. Reinsurance allows an insurer to write more insurance, or provide a higher limit of protection, than its capital assets would otherwise allow, which makes insurance more affordable.

  • The reinsurance market is global because insurers need to be able to diversify across the widest possible geographic area. More than 60 percent of the $59 billion in payments for the 2005 hurricane trio (Katrina, Rita and Wilma) came from foreign insurers and reinsurers, and the distribution of payments for the attack on the World Trade Center is similar.

 

Affiliate reinsurance is far more prevalent than non-affiliate reinsurance largely because it addresses the problems of adverse selection and moral hazard.
  • Affiliate reinsurance is a response to the problems of adverse selection and moral hazard. The insurer often knows more than the reinsurer about the risks it insures, and this information asymmetry creates an incentive for the insurer to transfer the worst risks and/or to be lax in its underwriting. If the insurer and reinsurer are part of the same corporate group, their incentives are better aligned: vertical integration "internalizes" the costs of adverse selection/moral hazard. This is especially important with respect to infrequent, high-loss events such as natural catastrophes, where the information asymmetry is most pronounced.

  • Moreover, as a tool for inter-company transfer of risks, affiliate reinsurance is central to the group structure of the insurance industry. Relative to non-affiliate reinsurance, affiliate reinsurance allows risk and capital to be moved more quickly and easily in response to changing market conditions.

  • Because affiliate reinsurance addresses real problems in the market, U.S.-owned insurance groups use it extensively: in 2009, nearly half of U.S.-owned insurers ceded at least 40 percent of their premiums to an affiliate, and a third of them ceded at least 80 percent.

 

The proposed tax would all but eliminate offshore affiliate reinsurance.
  • The legislation defines a benchmark above which offshore affiliate reinsurance is "excess" and thus subject to the tax. But the benchmark is both illogical and perverse, penalizing U.S. subsidiaries for their use of non-affiliate (as well as affiliate) reinsurance. Fully 87 percent of offshore affiliate reinsurance ($26.0 billion of $29.8 billion) would be classified as "excess."

  • The proposed tax -- roughly a 25 percent gross tax on "excess" premiums ceded offshore -- is confiscatory: it applies to revenue, not profits. Industry's pre-tax profits are only 9.9 percent of premiums over the last decade. Therefore, such a tax would force U.S. subsidiaries to eliminate all $26.0 billion of their "excess" offshore affiliate reinsurance.

 

U.S. homeowners and businesses would feel the effect of the tax in the form of reduced availability of, and higher prices for, P&C insurance.
  • We analyze financial data collected by the National Association of Insurance Commissioners on more than 700 large U.S. P&C firms over a ten-year period (1996-2006). Such information on past industry behavior is the best basis for predicting future industry behavior.

  • We first estimate the rate at which U.S. subsidiaries would replace their offshore affiliate reinsurance with capital and/or non-affiliate reinsurance, neither of which is a good substitute. Our key finding is that the net supply of reinsurance (non-affiliate and affiliate combined) would drop by 20 percent as a result of the proposed tax.

  • We then analyze how the industry as a whole would adjust to this new market environment (more capital, less reinsurance) in terms of the amount of insurance it would be willing to write. We estimate that the supply of insurance, as measured by insurance premiums, would drop by 2.1 - 2.4 percent, on average -- much more in some lines of business.

  • We observe the change in the price of insurance as a function of supply in our historical data. We estimate that the proposed tax would increase the price of insurance by 2.1 - 2.4 percent, on average, and as much as 9 percent in some lines of business. U.S. consumers would have to pay $11 - $13 billion more per year to obtain the same coverage.

  • Corresponding to the reduction in insurance premiums and the increase in insurance price, the insurance coverage (for future losses and expenses) drops by 4.1 - 4.8 percent, on average, and as much as 16 percent in some lines of business.

 

The effects of the tax would fall disproportionately on certain states and lines of business.
  • To calculate the variation in effects across states, we apply our estimated nationwide price increases to individual states, based on the value of premiums written in each state. The hardest-hit states (California, Florida, New York, Texas, New Jersey, Massachusetts and Louisiana) have large, diverse economies with huge exposure to property and liability losses.

  • The high-risk lines of business that benefit the most from the global diversification would see the largest price increases; these include commercial liability insurance, homeowners insurance in catastrophe-prone states, earthquake insurance, aircraft insurance, and reinsurance covering extreme losses.

 

Overall, the proposed tax would lead to a degradation of the ability of firms, both inside and outside of the P&C industry, to manage risk.
  • The current combination of tools (capital, affiliate and non-affiliate reinsurance) represents the P&C industry's optimal approach to risk management. If Congress were to limit or close off any one option, it would reduce industry's ability to manage its own risk. Limiting the use of offshore affiliate reinsurance in particular would drive U.S. subsidiaries away from the high-risk lines in which they specialize, thus restricting the supply of insurance to these lines.

  • Manufacturing, oil and chemical firms would have to pay more for insurance and could face restrictions on coverage. They would have to assume more risk just when their own capital structure is strained, leading to less investment and greater risk of insolvency.

  • Adoption of such a tax would be imprudent under the best of conditions. Under current conditions, with the risks due to natural catastrophes growing and the ability of government and private industry to absorb shocks still tentative due to an uncertain economic recovery, it seems especially unwise.

The Impact on the U.S. Insurance Market of H.R. 3424 on

 

Offshore Affiliate Reinsurance: An Updated Economic

 

Analysis1

 

 

Michael Cragg, J. David Cummins and Bin Zhou

 

 

I. INTRODUCTION

Congress is considering H.R. 3424, legislation introduced by Rep. Richard E. Neal (D-Mass) in 2009, which would impose a significant tax on reinsurance that a foreign-owned U.S. insurance company purchases from an affiliate located outside of the United States. Reinsurance -- insurance for insurance companies -- is a key tool for managing risk: much of the global demand for reinsurance comes from the United States, which has the world's largest insurance market and faces unique risks from natural disasters and the U.S. legal liability system. United States accounted for 76 percent of worldwide insured losses for natural catastrophes between 2000 and 2009, and it has been involved in each of the top 9 most costly insurance losses between 1970 and 2009.2

H.R. 3424 is a response to pressure from some insurance groups that are headquartered in the United States, who claim that the purchase of reinsurance from foreign affiliates is largely a tax-avoidance strategy by U.S. subsidiaries, and that the legislation is necessary to level the playing field. Supporters also claim that the legislation would have no adverse effect on U.S. consumers because, in their words, the affected transactions "add no additional capacity to the market, but rather require a mere bookkeeping entry to move premium from the U.S. company's pocket to the foreign parent's pocket . . ."

Opponents of the legislation counter that reinsurance represents a genuine transfer of risk and the associated losses from an insurer to a reinsurer, even if the two entities belong to the same corporate group. As evidence that affiliate reinsurance serves a valid non-tax business purpose, they note that U.S.-based insurance groups themselves make extensive use of it.3 Opponents also dispute the claim that consumers would not be harmed, predicting that the legislation would make property and casualty (P&C) insurance less available and affordable in the United States.

To help inform the debate, a coalition of insurance firms opposed to the legislation has asked us to examine the economic impact it would have on U.S. consumers. Toward that end, we analyze comprehensive financial data collected by the National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) on more than 700 large U.S. P&C firms over a ten-year period (1996 -- 2006). We use a three-step approach to estimate the direct effect of the proposed tax on the supply of reinsurance and the indirect effect on the supply and price of primary insurance.

We estimate that the legislation, which would impose roughly a 25 percent gross tax on almost all premiums ceded through offshore affiliate reinsurance, would have the following economic impact:

  • Reduce the supply of reinsurance, as measured by the insurance premiums, in the United States by $20 - $24 billion, which represents 20 percent of all reinsurance and nearly 40 percent of all foreign reinsurance (non-affiliated as well as affiliated);

  • Reduce the supply of primary insurance in the United States by 2.1 - 2.4 percent;

  • Increase the price of primary insurance by 2.1 - 2.4 percent, overall, and by close to 9 percent in some lines of business;

  • Reduce the insurance coverage by 4.1 - 4.8 percent, overall, and by 16 percent in some lines of business; and

  • As a result of higher prices, require U.S. consumers to pay $11 - $13 billion more per year to obtain the same insurance coverage.

 

Moreover, these estimates likely understate the real impact of the proposed tax, in part because our analysis of historical data does not take into account the current turmoil in capital markets.

We extend our analysis to measure the variation in the effects of the tax across states. First, we simply apply the estimated nationwide price increases to individual states, based on the value of premiums written in each state. For example, U.S. insurers wrote nearly $977 million of earthquake insurance in California in 2009. Based on the nationwide price increase for earthquake insurance (7.4 percent), Californians would have to pay an additional $72 million as a result of the tax. We present these results for 13 states and 18 lines of business in the report (impacts for all 50 states and District of Columbia are contained in Appendix B). Second, because our nationwide estimates significantly understate the impact of the tax on some markets, especially those catastrophe-related lines of business in the coastal states, we incorporate a proxy for state-level data on reinsurance to account for the role of foreign reinsurance in catastrophe prone areas. We estimate, by way of illustration, that Florida would see a 13 percent increase in the price of commercial multiple peril property insurance (compared to a 3 percent increase nationwide).

We conclude that H.R. 3424 would lead to a degradation of the ability of firms to manage risk, both inside and outside of the P&C industry. The financial burden of excess catastrophe risk, in particular, would fall more heavily on government. Adoption of such legislation would be imprudent under the best of conditions. Under current conditions, with the risks due to natural catastrophes growing and the ability of the government and private industry to absorb shocks still tentative due to an uncertain economic recovery, it seems especially unwise.

The report is organized as follows. In the next section (section II), we discuss the P&C industry and the important role of reinsurance, particularly affiliate reinsurance. Section III summarizes the current tax treatment of offshore affiliate reinsurance transactions and the proposal in H.R. 3424 to subject "excess" transactions to an extremely large tax. In section IV, we use the formula specified in the legislation to calculate the amount of insurance ceded to offshore affiliate reinsurers that would be deemed "excess." Section V summarizes our analysis of the economic impact of the proposed tax. (We provide a more technical description of our methodology in Appendix A.) In Section VI, we look at the state-level impact of the proposed tax. Finally, in section VII, we offer a brief conclusion.

II. P&C INSURANCE AND THE ROLE OF REINSURANCE

Property and casualty insurance protects businesses, homeowners and others against a wide range of risks, including earthquakes and hurricanes (property catastrophe), crop failure, workers' compensation claims, and general liability including class action lawsuits. In 2009, U.S. P&C insurers earned $428 billion in premiums and incurred $256 billion in claims and $173 billion in underwriting expenses.4

Insurance companies attempt to manage risks so that, on average, the premiums they collect minus their expenses equal or exceed the present value of their losses (i.e., their claims payments). For some lines of business, risk management is straightforward. For instance, millions of automobile drivers are insured every year and insurance companies can predict the annual rate of accidents and injuries and the magnitude of losses with a great deal of accuracy. For other lines of business, however, risk management is much more complex. For example, natural disasters such as hurricanes and earthquakes occur infrequently but impose catastrophic losses, making actuarial analysis much more challenging.

Risk management has become more complex in recent years. Prior to 1989, the U.S. insurance industry had never suffered a loss of more than $1 billion from a single disaster. That year, Hurricane Hugo cost insurers $7 billion, and numerous catastrophes since then, most of them natural disasters, have surpassed Hugo, as shown in Figure 1. In 1992, Hurricane Andrew caused $15 billion in insured losses in Florida and Louisiana, and State Farm's losses alone ($4.6 billion) were equal to the entire capital of State Farm P&C at the time. In 1994, insured residential losses from the Northridge earthquake in southern California (totaled $17 billion) exceeded the cumulative dollars ever collected for earthquake insurance in the state.5 In 2005, the trio of hurricanes that hit Florida and the Gulf Coast (Wilma, Rita, and Katrina) caused $59 billion in insured losses.6

 

Figure 1. Worldwide Catastrophe Losses (1970-2009)

 

 

 

 

Source: Swiss Re, "Natural Catastrophes and Man-Made Disasters in 2009: Catastrophes Claim Fewer Victims, Insured Losses Fall," Sigma Study No 1/2010.

The losses from natural disasters will almost certainly continue to grow because of the residential and commercial development that has occurred along coastlines and in other areas prone to earthquakes, hurricanes and floods: According to the U.S. Census Bureau, the population in hurricane exposed states will increase by 36.3 percent between 2000 and 2030, accounting for 53 percent of the increase in the entire U.S. population.7

In addition to the rise in catastrophe losses, the U.S. P&C industry has experienced several liability crises in recent decades, such as occurred due to asbestos and environmental litigation.8 And the U.S. businesses are continuing to face significant commercial liability for coverage on error and omissions, directors and officers, multiple peril, product liability, etc. Table 1 shows that U.S. is by far the largest commercial liability insurance market in the world, accounting for 54 percent of the worldwide market in 2008 ($77.2 out of $142 billion). Premiums spend on commercial liability coverage in the U.S. represents 0.54 percent of the GDP, more than any other country.

             Table 1. The Global Commercial Insurance Market, 2008

 

 

                   Premium Spent on

 

 Rank            Commercial Liability              GDP        Premium/GDP

 

 

 1 US                     77.2                   14,301           0.54%

 

 2 UK                     11.7                    2,673           0.44%

 

 3 Germany                11.6                    3,684           0.31%

 

 4 France                  6.9                    2,864           0.24%

 

 5 Canada                  4.9                    1,517           0.32%

 

 6 Italy                   4.9                    2,312           0.21%

 

 7 Japan                   4.7                    4,932           0.10%

 

 8 Australia               3.8                      966           0.39%

 

 9 Spain                   2.7                    1,614           0.17%

 

 10 China                  1.2                    4,478           0.03%

 

 

 Top 10                    129                   39,343           0.33%

 

                           142                   60,775           0.23%

 

 World

 

 

 Source: Swiss Re, "Commercial liability: a challenge for businesses and

 

 their insurers," Sigma No 5/2009.

 

The Critical Role of Capital and Reinsurance

 

The amount of insurance an individual P&C company can sell is partly a function of how much capital it maintains. The greater the volatility of its loss claims, the more capital the company will need to keep to satisfy regulators and rating agencies that it will be able to pay policyholder claims. Capital acts as a shock absorber for volatility -- it gets depleted when times are bad and accumulates when times are good.

Capital is a scarce resource in the insurance industry. When insurance companies are not able to cover their losses, or when lack of capital limits their ability to write insurance in the first place, the burden can fall to government and ultimately taxpayers. Effective management of capital is thus a primary concern of U.S. insurance regulators and rating agencies.

A substitute for capital -- and a critical tool for managing risk -- is reinsurance. Reinsurance is insurance for insurance companies. An insurer transfers (or cedes) premiums collected from customers to a reinsurer that agrees contractually to bear a portion of the insured losses. Because reinsurance transfers the actual risk, the insurer typically does not have to maintain capital or reserves to cover the losses it cedes.

There are two types of reinsurance: proportional and non-proportional. With proportional (or quota share) reinsurance, the reinsurer provides insurance for a fixed percentage of the primary insurer's losses. With non-proportional reinsurance, also known as excess-of-loss reinsurance, the reinsurer agrees to cover losses above a pre-determined threshold up to a pre-determined cap.

Most reinsurance of U.S. subsidiaries by foreign affiliates is proportional reinsurance. With proportional reinsurance, the reinsurer pays a "ceding commission" that covers the originating insurer's underwriting and administrative costs as well as its estimated lost profit potential.

Figure 2 shows the flow of payments in the hypothetical example of a 50-percent proportional reinsurance contract with a 30-percent ceding commission. The insurance company cedes half of the premium it receives from policyholders ($1000) to the reinsurer, for which it receives $300. When the insurer suffers a loss of $1500, the reinsurer provides 50-percent reimbursement.9

 

Figure 2. Insurance and Reinsurance

 

 

 

 

Reinsurance and Economic Efficiency

 

Reinsurance enhances the efficiency of the insurance market in several ways. First, reinsurance allows an insurance company to reduce the volatility of its losses and hence increase the amount of insurance it can support with its existing capital. Insurance companies accomplish this by laying off onto reinsurer's exposure to particular risks or concentrations of risk. Reinsurers can bear these risks more efficiently because they assume them from a variety of sources and because many of the risks are uncorrelated.

To illustrate, an insurance company that writes a substantial amount of California homeowners insurance can reduce the potential volatility of its losses by laying off on a reinsurer some of its exposure to losses from earthquakes. An insurance company that writes a substantial amount of Florida homeowners insurance can achieve the same goal by ceding to a reinsurer some of its exposure to losses from hurricanes. Because the occurrence of California earthquakes and Florida hurricanes is uncorrelated, the volatility of losses from the reinsurer's pool of risks, which includes both sets of exposures, will be lower than that from the pool of risks held by either of the primary insurers.

Not surprisingly, much of the demand for reinsurance comes from insurance companies in catastrophe-prone regions, which use it to insure their extreme risks. In addition to writing more business, an insurer covered by reinsurance can provide a higher limit of protection than its capital assets would otherwise allow. By allowing for more efficient use of capital, reinsurance makes the coverage of risk -- particularly, the risk of catastrophic losses -- more affordable.

A second way that reinsurance enhances economic efficiency is by facilitating the transfer of risk and capital within individual groups of affiliated insurance companies. As market conditions change, the relative profitability of insurance in different regions and lines of business shifts over time. Reinsurance allows the parent company to build capital in a centrally managed pool and then deploy it quickly to subsidiaries around the globe in response to these changing conditions. For instance, after Hurricanes Andrew and Katrina, foreign reinsurance companies quickly mobilized to replenish their capital base, which they used to fund additional risk-bearing entities and to support new business written by their U.S. subsidiaries and other entities.

This capital-generation function of reinsurance helps to lessen the effects of the cycles and crises to which the insurance industry is susceptible.10 Following catastrophic losses in 2004 and 2005, reinsurers raised about $30 billion in new capital, including through new equity capital for startup companies, seasoned equity issues and catastrophe bonds.11 Despite the large unexpected losses, reinsurance prices began to soften as early as the end of 2006 and the beginning of 2007.

Third, reinsurance enhances the efficiency of the insurance market by channeling risk to entities that have highly specialized expertise. For example, Bermuda's reinsurers specialize in the highly volatile lines of business characterized by large, infrequent claims, such as hurricanes and earthquakes and class action lawsuits. They provide sophisticated data analysis and risk modeling capabilities critical to helping insurers understand how diversification affects their expected losses and capital requirements. Small insurance companies in particular benefit from the technical and financial expertise that these specialty reinsurance companies provide.

 

The Importance of Foreign Reinsurance

 

The reinsurance market is global because the insurance industry needs to be able to diversify risk across the widest possible geographic area. U.S. insurers in particular must be able to diversify across the globe because the United States represents such a large concentration of insured risk. Access to foreign reinsurance allows U.S. insurers to provide greater amounts of coverage to U.S. consumers at more affordable prices.

This critical reliance on foreign reinsurance by the United States can be seen in several ways: concentration of insurable loss, recovery experience, and reinsurance premiums ceded to foreign reinsurers. First, the United States accounted for 76 percent of worldwide insured losses from natural catastrophes between 2000 and 2009 (Figure 3). Its annual share of the worldwide insured losses ranges from 30 percent in 2007 to over 90 percent in 2005. In 2005 alone, the total U.S. insured losses exceeded $100 billion (in 2009 dollars).

 

Figure 3. U.S. Insured Catastrophe Losses (2000 - 2009)

 

 

 

 

Source: Swiss Re, Natural Catastrophes and Man-Made Disasters.

Furthermore, eight of the most costly catastrophes in the U.S. occurred in the last ten years (Table 2). The importance of foreign reinsurance for the United States market, in particular the natural catastrophes, can simply not be overemphasized.

          Table 2. Top 10 Most Costly Insurance Losses (1970 - 2009)

 

 

                                                                 Insured losses

 

                                                                  (Millions in

 

 Date (start)           Event                    Country          2009 Dollars)

 

 

 Aug. 2005    Hurricane Katrina; floods,    US, Gulf of Mexico,        71,163

 

              dams burst, damage to         Bahamas, North

 

              oil rigs                      Atlantic

 

 

 Aug. 1992    Hurricane Andrew; floods      US, Bahamas                24,479

 

 

 Sept. 2001   Terror attack on WTC,         US                         22,767

 

              Pentagon, and  other

 

              buildings

 

 

 Jan. 1994    Northridge earthquake         US                         20,276

 

              (M 6.6)

 

 

 Sept. 2008   Hurricane Ike; floods,        US, Caribbean,             19,940

 

              offshore damage               Gulf of Mexico et al

 

 

 Sept. 2004   Hurricane Ivan;               US, Caribbean,             14,642

 

              damage to oil rigs            Barbados et al

 

 

 Oct. 2005    Hurricane Wilma; floods       US, Mexico, Jamaica,       13,807

 

                                            Haiti et al

 

 

 Sept. 2005   Hurricane Rita; floods,       US, Gulf of Mexico,        11,809

 

              damage to oil rigs            Cuba

 

 

 Aug. 2004    Hurricane Charley; floods     US, Cuba, Jamaica et al     9,148

 

 

 Sept. 1991    Typhoon Mireille / No 19     Japan                       8,899

 

 

 Note: Swiss Re, "Natural Catastrophes and Man-Made Disasters in 2009:

 

 Catastrophes Claim Fewer Victims, Insured Losses Fall," Sigma Study No

 

 1/2010.

 

 

Second, the United States' heavily concentrated catastrophe risk is also borne out in the fact that U.S. businesses and customers have recovered billions of dollars of losses from foreign insurers and reinsurers. Figure 4 shows the regional distribution of insurance payments for the 2005 hurricane trio (Wilma, Rita, and Katrina). More than 60 percent of the roughly $59 billion in insurance payments came from foreign insurers and reinsurers. The distribution of payments for the attack on the World Trade Center is similar.12

 

Figure 4. Regional Distribution of 2005

 

Hurricane Insurance Payments

 

 

 

 

Source: J. David Cummins, "The Bermuda Insurance Market: An Economic Analysis," 2008.

Finally, while the United States has the largest insurance market in the world, roughly half of the $100 billion in reinsurance purchased by U.S. insurers comes from non-U.S. reinsurers13 (Figure 5). The fraction of foreign reinsurance is higher for high-risk lines of business, such as commercial liability insurance, homeowners insurance in catastrophe-prone states, earthquake insurance, and reinsurance covering extreme losses. For example, foreign reinsurers account for two-thirds of U.S. property catastrophe reinsurance.14 In the state of Florida, Bermuda reinsurers provided 70 percent of the private reinsurance to the Florida domestic company home insurance market in 2008, and foreign reinsurers altogether provided 94 percent.15

 

Figure 5. U.S. P&C Reinsurance and Foreign Reinsurers

 

 

 

 

Source: Highline database (reinsurance ceded) and RAA (foreign reinsurers' percentages).

A key reason for U.S.'s heavy reliance on foreign reinsurance is that foreign reinsurers are more nimble and better able to raise capital in a global market than U.S.-owned firms, which are handicapped by our country's state-dominated insurance regulatory system. The licensing process is lengthy and complex, which makes it almost impossible for a start-up insurer or reinsurer to enter the U.S. market in a timely fashion to serve a new insurance need. And because regulation makes it difficult for insurers to quickly adjust rates or coverage terms, U.S. firms have shied away from the highly volatile risks that Bermuda firms have in turn embraced. Moreover, although large U.S. corporations often export these extreme risks to international underwriting centers such as London and Bermuda primarily to achieve geographic diversification, they also seek to avoid the fragmentation of the U.S. regulatory system.16

 

The Importance of Affiliate Reinsurance

 

U.S. P&C companies rely heavily on other companies in the same insurance group (i.e., affiliates) for reinsurance. Table 3 shows the distribution of U.S.-owned P&C insurers in terms of the fraction of premiums received from their customers that they ceded to a related reinsurer in 2008. Nearly half of the U.S.-owned insurers ceded at least 40 percent of their premiums to an affiliate, and more than a third of them ceded at least 80 percent.

               Table 3. Distribution of U.S.-Owned P&C Companies by

 

                  Net Premiums Ceded to Related Reinsurers as

 

                        a Percent of Gross Premiums

 

 

   Net Premiums Ceded to             Number of              Percent of

 

 Affiliates/Gross Premiums           Companies            All Companies

 

 

      >= 0%                              677                   100%

 

      > 10%                              413                    61%

 

      > 20%                              385                    57%

 

      > 30%                              365                    54%

 

      > 40%                              350                    52%

 

      > 50%                              330                    49%

 

      > 60%                              302                    45%

 

      > 70%                              284                    42%

 

      > 80%                              253                    37%

 

      > 90%                              213                    31%

 

 

 Notes:

 

 

      (1) The sample includes only companies that belong to a U.S.-owned

 

 insurance group which has at least $500 million in gross written premiums

 

 (GWP) in 2008. Companies with less than $10 million in annual GWP in 2009 were

 

 excluded in an effort to eliminate laragely inactive companies.

 

 

      (2) Foreign control is defined here as 50 percent or greater ownership by

 

 foreign persons.

 

 

      (3) Net premiums ceded to affiliates equals reinsurance premiums ceded to

 

 affiliates less reinsurance premiums assumed from affiliates. Gross premiums

 

 are defined here as direct insurance premiums written plus written assumed

 

 reinsurance premiums from unrelated insurance companies

 

 

 Source: Horst Frisch Incorporated. Tabulations of data from the Highline Data

 

 U.S. P&C Insurance database.

 

 

It is not hard to understand why affiliate reinsurance would play a central role in the insurance market. After all, the key rationale for reinsurance -- namely, risk pooling and diversification -- applies no less when the reinsurance is provided by an affiliate within a related group of insurance companies than when it is provided by a non-affiliated reinsurer. Absent reinsurance, regulators would require each company within an insurance group to have enough capital on a standalone basis to support the business it writes. With affiliate reinsurance, a group of related companies can reduce the total amount of capital needed to support their combined business.

One must look beyond this common risk-pooling function, however, to understand why affiliate reinsurance is so much more prevalent than non-affiliate reinsurance. Most important, affiliate reinsurance is a response to the problems of adverse selection and moral hazard.17 These problems arise because the insurer often knows more than the reinsurer about the risks it insures, and this information asymmetry creates an incentive for the insurer to transfer the worst risks to the reinsurer (adverse selection) and/or to be lax in its underwriting (one form of moral hazard). If the insurer and the reinsurer are part of the same corporate group, their incentives are better aligned. Stated differently, vertical integration serves to "internalize" the costs of adverse selection and moral hazard.18 This is especially beneficial with respect to the coverage of low-frequency, high-loss events such as natural catastrophes and product liability lawsuits, where the information asymmetry between the insurer and reinsurer is most pronounced.

Second, as a tool for inter-company transfer of risks, affiliate reinsurance is central to the group structure of the insurance industry. As discussed above, insurance groups organize subsidiaries around the world in order to diversify risk across the widest possible geographic area. Use of affiliate reinsurance allows an insurance group to transfer risk far more quickly and easily than it could with non-affiliate reinsurance, which requires lengthy negotiations with a third party over the terms and price of the contract -- a contract that typically must be renegotiated annually. Because of its greater flexibility, affiliate reinsurance is also less susceptible to price increases and supply restrictions over the hard-market phase of the underwriting cycle.

These two explanations are closely linked. Affiliate reinsurance allows for the relatively rapid transfer of risk in large part because the costs of adverse selection and moral hazard have been internalized. Conversely, negotiations over non-affiliate reinsurance are complex and time consuming largely because a third-party reinsurer must scrutinize potential risks for evidence of these problems. To be sure, non-affiliate reinsurers have devised mechanisms to reduce the cost of adverse selection and moral hazard. These mechanisms are not perfect, however. Moreover, they are expensive, which raises the cost of non-affiliate reinsurance.

III. TAX TREATMENT OF OFFSHORE AFFILIATE REINSURANCE: CURRENT LAW AND PROPOSED CHANGE

Currently, an offshore reinsurer that derives income abroad from reinsuring risks that originate in the United States is generally not subject to U.S. federal income tax. For example, if a U.S. insurer cedes $1,000 in premiums and receives a 30 percent ($300) ceding commission, income on the net premium ceded of $700 is earned and taxed abroad, because that is where the risk resides. (See Figure 6.) Bermuda reinsurers, however, pay a one percent U.S. federal excise tax on the full amount of the ceded premiums ($1,000 in our example).19

The U.S. insurer in this example can deduct the gross premium ceded ($1,000) from its U.S. federal income tax return but it must treat the ceding commission ($300) as taxable income. Moreover, the U.S. insurer foregoes the deduction for losses ($750) that it would have been able to take had it not ceded that risk to the reinsurer. Over time, the deduction for the ceded premium tends to be fully offset because, with actuarially fair insurance, expected losses plus underwriting expenses are equal to premiums plus investment income.

 

Figure 6. Offshore Reinsurance

 

 

 

 

H.R. 3424

 

The legislation would limit the tax deductibility of premiums that foreign-owned U.S. insurers (U.S. subsidiaries) cede to affiliate reinsurers offshore.20 Specifically, the legislation creates a benchmark, known as the "industry fraction," which represents the average industry level of non-affiliate reinsurance by line of business. When the share of premiums ceded to an offshore reinsurer (non-affiliate as well as affiliate) by a U.S. subsidiary exceeds this industry fraction, the "excess" affiliate reinsurance is taxable as corporate income.

On the face of it, the legislation raises significant concerns. First, the use of industrywide reliance on non-affiliate reinsurance as the relevant benchmark is illogical. If, as supporters of the legislation claim, U.S. subsidiaries are relying excessively on (offshore) affiliate reinsurance in order to reap tax benefits, then the logical benchmark would be some measure of reliance on affiliate reinsurance. It would appear that the legislative drafters chose an illogical benchmark because it has the effect of setting the bar for what is considered "excess" very low and as will be shown shortly, effectively excludes foreign insurance companies.

Second, the application of the benchmark is perverse. Because non-affiliated reinsurance is counted first against the permissible threshold, the proposal penalizes those U.S. subsidiaries that are most reliant on non-affiliate reinsurance. Figure 7 below illustrates this phenomenon. In each scenario, a U.S. subsidiary has written $100 in premiums, of which it has ceded half ($50) to offshore reinsurers, both affiliate and non-affiliate. The threshold above which offshore affiliate reinsurance is taxed is assumed to be $30. Firm 1 cedes $20 to non-affiliate reinsurers; thus some of its affiliate reinsurance ($10 out of $30) falls below the threshold and escapes the tax. Firm 2 cedes $35 to non-affiliate reinsurers; thus all of its affiliate reinsurance exceeds the threshold. This outcome makes no economic sense.

 

Figure 7. Determination of Excess Premium

 

 

 

 

Moreover, U.S. subsidiaries already make extensive use of non-affiliate reinsurance -- it accounts for more than two fifths ($22 billion) of the $52 billion in reinsurance that they purchase. That, together with the low industry fraction, ensures that most of the premiums that U.S. subsidiaries cede to offshore affiliate reinsurers would fall above the threshold.

Third, the tax is extremely large. Under the example in Figure 6 above, if the U.S. insurer is foreign-owned and the foreign reinsurer is a related company, the net premium ceded of $700 would no longer be deductible and hence would be subject to U.S. income tax (assuming the transaction is "excess"). Since the corporate income tax rate is 35 percent, the proposal amounts to a 24.5 percent gross tax on the $1,000 premium ceded offshore (700 x 0.35 / 1,000 = 0.245).21

To put this into perspective, note that the pre-tax income of the U.S. P&C industry has been 9.9 percent of premiums on average over the last ten years.22 Thus, the proposed tax on "excess" premiums far exceeds the average pre-tax income that U.S. insurers earn per dollar of premium. Far from "leveling the playing field," such a tax is confiscatory.

In sum, the legislation imposes a confiscatory tax on offshore affiliate reinsurance deemed to be "excess." Moreover, it defines "excess" in an illogical way. It is hard to discern a legitimate economic rationale for such an approach.

IV. HOW MUCH PREMIUM WOULD BE SUBJECT TO THE TAX?

In this section, we carry out a set of straightforward calculations to show the amount of insurance ceded by U.S. insurers to offshore affiliate reinsurers that would be considered "excess" and therefore subject to the proposed tax. First, we calculate the benchmark "industry fraction" for each line of business. Next we identify the foreign-owned insurance groups that do business in the United States and calculate the value of the insurance premiums ceded to offshore affiliates by their U.S. subsidiaries. Finally, we combine the first two calculations to show the amount of offshore affiliate reinsurance that would be deemed "excess" under the legislation and therefore subject to the proposed tax.

 

Calculation of the "Industry Fraction"

 

We first calculate the "industry fraction" for each line of business and overall. To do this, we use 2009 aggregate industry data on premiums in five categories, as shown in Table 4.23 Included in the data are all large U.S. insurers, including U.S. subsidiaries of foreign-owned insurance groups, which report to the National Association of Insurance Commissioners. Column 1, "direct business," records the amount of premiums written directly to policyholders. Columns 2 and 3 show the amount of "reinsurance assumed" by NAIC-reporting firms from affiliates and non-affiliates, respectively. Columns 4 and 5 show the amount of "reinsurance ceded" by NAIC-reporting firms to the same two subgroups.

                     Table 4. Calculation of Industry Fraction

 

                           (2009, $ in Millions)

 

 

                                   1           Reins. Assumed      Reins. Ceded

 

                                                2           3            4

 

 

                                 Direct       From        From           To

 

                                Business   Affiliates   Non-Affil.   Affiliates

 

 

 Fire                             12,661          559       2,544         1,973

 

 Allied lines                     21,360          884       5,157         2,048

 

 Farmowners multiple peril         2,824           46         223           145

 

 Homeowners multiple peril        67,497          292       1,941         2,361

 

 Commercial multiple peril        34,000          625       1,339         2,722

 

 Mortgage guaranty                 5,435           41          (0)          144

 

 Ocean marine                      3,740          327         770           962

 

 Inland marine                    13,408          326         497         1,315

 

 Financial guaranty                1,916        3,169         (74)        3,206

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- occurrence         2,279          (32)        110            76

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- claims made        8,463           46         455           926

 

 Earthquake                        1,988           65         322           402

 

 Group accident and health         4,021          493         891           605

 

 Credit accident and health

 

   (group and indiv.)                245           25          98            66

 

 Other accident and health         3,203            1         299           781

 

 Workers' compensation            37,558          313       1,467         2,968

 

 Other liability --

 

   occurrence                     28,215          568       2,445         3,733

 

 Other liability -- claims

 

   made                           18,019          780       1,990         3,470

 

 Excess workers'

 

   compensation                      917           17         241            96

 

 Products liability --

 

   occurrence                      2,425          102          91           431

 

 Products liability --

 

   claims made                       457           31          15            63

 

 Private passenger auto

 

   liability                      98,306        1,172       2,349         3,246

 

 Commercial auto liability        18,841          141       1,005         1,403

 

 Auto physical damage             71,552          453       1,308         3,515

 

 Aircraft (all perils)             1,989          195         499           607

 

 Fidelity                          1,120           60         100            72

 

 Surety                            5,193          265         510           557

 

 Burglary and theft                  168            3          14            18

 

 Boiler and machinery              1,373          117       1,143           251

 

 Credit                            1,889          108         304           595

 

 International                        63            9         155            60

 

 Warranty                          2,654           40          59           302

 

 Reinsurance -- Nonprop.

 

   Assumed Property                  XXX          150       8,103         1,213

 

 Reinsurance -- Nonprop.

 

   Assumed Liability                 XXX           34       7,538         1,405

 

 Reinsurance -- Nonprop.

 

   Assumed Financial                 XXX            2         294            54

 

 Agg. Write-ins for Other

 

   Lines of Business               1,438          101         104           150

 

 

      Totals                     475,219       11,528      44,306        41,945

 

 

                               [table continued]

 

 

                            Reins. Ceded

 

                                                6            7             8

 

                                  5         Net Prem.

 

                                             Written       Gross       Industry

 

                                 To         1 + 2 + 3    Premiums      Fraction

 

                              Non-Affil.      - 4 - 5       1 + 3         5 / 7

 

 

 Fire                              3,553       10,238      15,205         23.4%

 

 Allied lines                     13,555       11,797      26,517         51.1%

 

 Farmowners multiple peril           331        2,616       3,047         10.9%

 

 Homeowners multiple peril         8,861       58,508      69,438         12.8%

 

 Commercial multiple peril         4,299       28,943      35,339         12.2%

 

 Mortgage guaranty                   768        4,564       5,435         14.1%

 

 Ocean marine                        929        2,946       4,510         20.6%

 

 Inland marine                     4,225        8,691      13,905         30.4%

 

 Financial guaranty                   12        1,793       1,842          0.6%

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- occurrence           153        2,127       2,389          6.4%

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- claims made          953        7,085       8,918         10.7%

 

 Earthquake                          671        1,301       2,309         29.0%

 

 Group accident and health           773        4,027       4,912         15.7%

 

 Credit accident and health

 

   (group and indiv.)                109          194         343         31.7%

 

 Other accident and health           285        2,437       3,502          8.1%

 

 Workers' compensation             4,114       32,257      39,025         10.5%

 

 Other liability --

 

   occurrence                      5,797       21,698      30,660         18.9%

 

 Other liability -- claims

 

   made                            2,895       14,425      20,010         14.5%

 

 Excess workers'

 

   compensation                      138          941       1,159         11.9%

 

 Products liability --

 

   occurrence                        193        1,993       2,516          7.7%

 

 Products liability --

 

   claims made                        68          372         472         14.3%

 

 Private passenger auto

 

   liability                       3,542       95,039     100,656          3.5%

 

 Commercial auto liability         1,982       16,601      19,846         10.0%

 

 Auto physical damage              1,808       67,990      72,860          2.5%

 

 Aircraft (all perils)               852        1,224       2,488         34.2%

 

 Fidelity                            109        1,099       1,220          8.9%

 

 Surety                              535        4,876       5,703          9.4%

 

 Burglary and theft                   13          153         182          7.3%

 

 Boiler and machinery                578        1,804       2,516         23.0%

 

 Credit                              480        1,225       2,193         21.9%

 

 International                        25          143         219         11.6%

 

 Warranty                            693        1,757       2,713         25.5%

 

 Reinsurance -- Nonprop.

 

   Assumed Property                  830        6,210       8,103         10.2%

 

 Reinsurance -- Nonprop.

 

   Assumed Liability                 846        5,321       7,538         11.2%

 

 Reinsurance -- Nonprop.

 

   Assumed Financial                   6          236         294          1.9%

 

 Agg. Write-ins for Other

 

   Lines of Business                 212        1,281       1,542         13.7%

 

 

      Totals                      65,193      423,916     519,526         12.5%

 

 

 Highline Database.

 

 

H.R. 3424 defines "industry fraction" as the amount of premium ceded to non-affiliate reinsurers, both domestic and offshore (column 5), divided by gross premiums (column 7). The proposals define gross premiums as the sum of direct business (column 1) and reinsurance assumed from non-affiliate insurers (column 3). Gross premiums, by this definition, represent a measure of the amount of insurance written by U.S. P&C companies -- both as primary insurers covering direct insureds and as reinsurers covering non-affiliate insurers.

Our calculation of the industry fraction is shown in column 8. Although there is considerable variation across the 36 lines of business,24 the average industry fraction -- that is, the average level of reliance on non-affiliate reinsurance industrywide -- is only 12.5 percent. Moreover, the industry fraction for four of the top five lines of business, as measured by gross premiums, is even less than 12.5 percent: private passenger auto liability (3.5 percent), auto physical damage (2.5 percent), workers' compensation (10.5 percent), and commercial multiple peril (12.2). The industry fraction of 12.8 percent for homeowners multiple peril, the third largest line of business, is only slightly above the overall average of 12.5 percent.25

 

Amount of Insurance Ceded by U.S. Affiliates

 

Next we identify the foreign-owned insurance groups that do business in the United States and calculate the value of the insurance premiums ceded offshore by their U.S. subsidiaries by line of business. This step requires us to make two assumptions.

First, the relevant data on cessions is available only for the consolidated U.S. operation of an insurance group, whereas the information on foreign ownership is available only for individual U.S. insurance companies. To determine whether a consolidated U.S. operation is foreign- or domestic-owned, we calculate the average level of foreign ownership of all the U.S. members of an insurance group (we use a direct-premiums-weighted average). We treat an insurance group (and its respective consolidated U.S. operation) as foreign-owned if this figure is equal to or greater than 25 percent.26

Second, the information on individual companies, which is recorded in the format of Table 4 above, does not specify whether reinsurance is ceded offshore or onshore. Thus, we assume that, in the case of a foreign-owned U.S. entity, any and all of the premiums it cedes to affiliates go offshore.

Table 5 below provides data on the U.S. operations of foreign-owned insurance groups. Column 4 shows the value of the insurance that these U.S. subsidiaries cede to offshore affiliates by line of business. Overall, U.S. subsidiaries cede $29.8 billion in premiums to offshore affiliate reinsurers.

        Table 5. Summary of U.S. Operations of Foreign-Owned Insurers

 

                              ($ in Millions)

 

 

                                                Reins. Assumed     Reins. Ceded

 

 

                                 Direct       From        From           To

 

                                Business   Affiliates   Non-Affil.   Affiliates

 

 

                                   (1)         (2)         (3)           (4)

 

 

 Fire                             2,659           212       1,466         1,376

 

 Allied lines                     5,911           504       2,693         1,588

 

 Farmowners multiple peril          180             0         128            87

 

 Homeowners multiple peril        8,427            46       1,116         2,029

 

 Commercial multiple peril        8,246           418         919         2,582

 

 Mortgage guaranty                    0             0           0             0

 

 Ocean marine                     1,121            50         434           475

 

 Inland marine                    2,410           114         255           877

 

 Financial guaranty                 989           504          85           673

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- occurrence          111             0          68            30

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- claims made         786            12         185           350

 

 Earthquake                         870           119         219           436

 

 Group accident and health        1,084             3         651           480

 

 Credit accident and health

 

   (group and indiv.)                 0             1           0             2

 

 Other accident and health           63            60         127           146

 

 Workers' compensation            6,090           113         465         2,120

 

 Other liability --

 

   occurrence                     7,827           378       1,581         2,979

 

 Other liability -- claims

 

   made                           6,332           148       1,088         3,275

 

 Excess workers'

 

   compensation                     247             0          62           102

 

 Products liability --

 

   occurrence                       774            53          62           411

 

 Products liability --

 

   claims made                      104             4           7            66

 

 Private passenger auto

 

   liability                      9,196           326         614         2,368

 

 Commercial auto liability        3,580           102         504         1,080

 

 Auto physical damage             6,891           161         419         2,153

 

 Aircraft (all perils)              942            -3         227           405

 

 Fidelity                           141             0          25            59

 

 Surety                             922            76         309           457

 

 Burglary and theft                  25             0          10            15

 

 Boiler and machinery               252            16         794           164

 

 Credit                             667            80         145           327

 

 International                       27             1          38            26

 

 Warranty                           489            36          37           101

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   property                           0             5       2,954         1,111

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   liability                          0             5       4,039         1,285

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assm

 

   financial lines                    0            -1         187            51

 

 Write-ins for other

 

   lines of business                282             0          21           108

 

 

      TOTALS                     77,645         3,544      16,552        29,794

 

 

                               [table continued]

 

 

                             Reins. Ceded              Excess as %

 

                                  To          Excess   of Offshore

 

                               Non-Affil     Premiums  Affil Reins

 

                                  (5)           (6)    (7)=(6)/(4)

 

 

 Fire                               919         1,126       81.8%

 

 Allied lines                     3,937           774       48.7%

 

 Farmowners multiple peril           25            74       85.2%

 

 Homeowners multiple peril        1,517         1,749       86.2%

 

 Commercial multiple peril        1,268         2,314       89.6%

 

 Mortgage guaranty                    0             0       76.0%

 

 Ocean marine                       229           379       79.7%

 

 Inland marine                      576           618       70.5%

 

 Financial guaranty                   9           672       99.9%

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- occurrence            6            27       91.2%

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- claims made         157           325       92.8%

 

 Earthquake                         363           377       86.6%

 

 Group accident and health          377           435       90.5%

 

 Credit accident and health

 

   (group and indiv.)                 0             1       90.7%

 

 Other accident and health           34           142       97.2%

 

 Workers' compensation              966         2,035       96.0%

 

 Other liability --

 

   occurrence                     2,007         2,736       91.8%

 

 Other liability -- claims

 

   made                           1,045         2,944       89.9%

 

 Excess workers'

 

   compensation                      50            83       81.6%

 

 Products liability --

 

   occurrence                       100           397       96.5%

 

 Products liability --

 

   claims made                       15            59       89.2%

 

 Private passenger auto             230         2,158       91.1%

 

   liability                        668         1,032       95.6%

 

 Commercial auto liability          337         2,073       96.3%

 

 Auto physical damage               303           268       66.2%

 

 Aircraft (all perils)               21            58       97.9%

 

 Fidelity                           118           415       90.8%

 

 Surety                               2            14       91.5%

 

 Burglary and theft                 107           116       70.6%

 

 Boiler and machinery               103           240       73.4%

 

 Credit                              13            22       86.1%

 

 International

 

 Warranty                           169            94       92.8%

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   property                         334           977       88.0%

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   liability                        509         1,109       86.3%

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assm

 

   financial lines                    3            50       97.0%

 

 Write-ins for other

 

   lines of business                 37            92       85.5%

 

 

      TOTALS                      21,933       25,986       87.2%

 

 

 Source: Authors' calculation based on data from Highline. Excess premiums (6)

 

 are sums of excess premiums for each foreign-owned company and each line of

 

 business.

 

Amount of Ceded Insurance Subject to H.R. 3424

 

Table 5 also shows, by line of business, the amount of this offshore affiliate reinsurance that would be deemed "excess" under the legislation and therefore subject to a 35 percent corporate income tax. (See columns 6 and 7.) Overall, $26.0 billion, or 87.2 percent, of the $29.8 billion in offshore affiliate reinsurance would be subject to the tax. Stated differently, only $3.8 billion, or 12.8 percent, of the total supply of offshore affiliate reinsurance would escape the proposed tax.

Certain lines of business would be especially vulnerable to the tax, as measured by the fraction of offshore affiliate reinsurance that would be considered "excess": workers' compensation (96.0 percent), "other liability -- occurrence" (91.8 percent), and "other liability -- claims made" (89.9 percent). Non-proportional (excess-of-loss) reinsurance for property, liability, and financial also would be disproportionately harmed, with 88.0, 86.3, and 97.0 percent of offshore affiliate reinsurance, respectively, deemed "excess."27 These are the very lines of business for which diversification through reinsurance is most important.

IV. ANALYSIS OF ECONOMIC IMPACT

In this section, we analyze the economic impact of the proposed tax on offshore affiliate reinsurance through a statistical analysis of comprehensive NAIC financial data. We use a three-step approach that combines regression analysis with a mathematical simulation of the U.S. insurance market to estimate the effect of the tax on the supply of reinsurance (step one) and on the supply and price of primary insurance (steps two and three). Our base-case analysis produces a lower-bound estimate of the impact of the tax because we do not constrain how U.S. subsidiaries can respond to it. We then modify the analysis to include a constraint on their response that is implicit in the legislation. That modification to our base-case gives us an upper-bound estimate. (See Appendix A for a technical description of our methodology.)

 

Impact on the Supply of Reinsurance (Step One)

 

In step one of our analysis, we estimate the direct effect of the proposed tax on the supply of reinsurance. First, as we calculated in the last section, 87.2 percent, or $26.0 billion, of offshore affiliate reinsurance would be considered "excess" under the legislation. Moreover, as we showed in section III, the proposed tax on "excess" premiums far exceeds the average pre-tax income that U.S. insurers earn per dollar of premium. Thus, it is reasonable to assume that U.S. subsidiaries would eliminate all $26.0 billion of their "excess" offshore affiliate reinsurance.

Of course, U.S. subsidiaries would partially offset this loss of offshore affiliate reinsurance by raising their level of capital and/or non-affiliate reinsurance, so as to maintain their existing book of business. Neither is a perfect substitute for affiliate reinsurance, however. Compared to reinsurance of any kind, capital is more expensive because it does not provide for diversification, and it is less flexible because it carries a greater regulatory burden. Likewise, non-affiliate reinsurance is more expensive than affiliate reinsurance, because it entails additional transaction costs, including the costs of adverse selection and moral hazard.

To estimate the net impact of this "offset" process, we calculate the level of substitution between affiliate insurance on the one hand, and capital and non-affiliate reinsurance on the other. We analyze some 7,400 observations from the NAIC data, each of which represents a financing decision made by a U.S. insurer between 1996 and 2006.28 We control statistically for the level of risk facing individual firms by taking into account risk-related measures such as the insurer's business mix, the geographic concentration of its business, and the size and age of the firm.

We estimate that, for each dollar of affiliate reinsurance that is lost, insurers would substitute 29 cents worth of non-affiliate reinsurance and 56 cents worth of capital, assuming that the supply of insurance remained constant.29 This implies that the $26.0 billion drop in affiliate reinsurance would be offset by a $7.5 billion increase in non-affiliate reinsurance and a $14.6 billion increase in capital. Thus, assuming a constant supply of insurance, imposition of the proposed tax would lead to a net loss of $18.5 billion in reinsurance ($26.0 billion less $7.5 billion).30

When we relax the assumption that the insurance supply remains constant, our estimate of the net loss in reinsurance increases somewhat -- to $20.4 billion. (We do not actually relax this assumption until step two of our analysis, but we report the results here for clarity of exposition.) That is a significant decline: it represents about one-fifth of all the reinsurance purchased by U.S. insurers and nearly 40 percent of all the foreign reinsurance supplied to the United States.

For certain lines of business, the proposed tax would lead to an even higher percentage loss, as shown in Figure 8.31 For example, approximately half of the excess-of-loss reinsurance for liability and property would be eliminated. More generally, the lines of business that would be most affected by the tax are the ones that benefit the most from the global pooling of risks that reinsurance provides.

 

Figure 8. Impact of H.R. 3424 on Affiliate

 

and Non-Affiliate Reinsurance

 

 

 

Note: Both percentages are calculated based on total reinsurance for the particular line of business.

 

Impact on the Supply of Insurance (Step Two)

 

In step two of our analysis, we trace the impact of a tax on offshore affiliate reinsurance through to its effect on the supply of primary insurance. First, we use regression analysis to estimate the impact on the insurance supply of the two direct effects we identified in step one--namely, a net decrease in the supply of reinsurance purchased by U.S. insurers and an increase in their supply of capital. Specifically, we employ a statistical model that measures the percent change in total insurance written as a function of the percent change in both reinsurance and capital. We use the same basic sample of companies that we analyzed in step one, although we drop those companies for which we lack sufficient data to measure a change in their behavior over time.

Our regression analysis indicates that the supply of primary insurance would drop by 0.68 percent for each 1 percent decrease in the amount of reinsurance purchased by U.S. insurers and would go up by 0.36 percent for each 1 percent increase in the amount of capital they maintain. Overall, these results accord well with economic intuition: one would expect a unit decrease in reinsurance to cause the supply of insurance to drop by more than the equivalent increase in capital would cause it to rise, because of the greater "leverage" that reinsurance provides relative to capital.

Although our regression analysis captures part of the process by which the insurance market would respond to the proposed tax on offshore affiliate reinsurance, it does not capture all of it. Specifically, while the supply of primary insurance would drop in response to the combination of direct effects analyzed above (less reinsurance and more capital), the drop in the insurance supply would in turn reduce the need for capital and reinsurance. (See Figure 9.)

 

Figure 9. Simulation of Impact of Proposed Legislation

 

on U.S. Insurance Market

 

 

 

 

To reflect this dynamic process, we develop a mathematical simulation of the P&C market that captures the simultaneous changes in reinsurance, capital and insurance premiums. The simulation begins with 2009 figures on premiums written and reinsurance purchased by U.S. insurers by line of business. We use the results of our two regression analyses to calculate aggregate figures for the amount of non-affiliate insurance and capital that U.S. subsidiaries would substitute to offset the loss of foreign affiliate reinsurance. We simulate as well the decrease in reinsurance and capital that would follow from the drop in premiums written.

Based on this dynamic-effects simulation, we calculate that the overall supply of insurance would decline from $531 billion to $520 billion, a drop of $11 billion or about 2.1 percent overall. Table 6 shows our results by line of business. (The last two columns will be discussed in the next sub-section.)

             Table 6. Impact on U.S. P&C Industry -- Lower Bound

 

                              ($ in Millions)

 

 

                                  2009                         Lower Bound

 

 

                                  Total

 

                                 Premium       Total                 Change in

 

                                 Written       Reins                Total Reins

 

                                  (TPW)        Ceded        TPW          Ceded

 

 

 Fire                             15,764        5,526    15,267           (930)

 

 Allied lines                     27,401       15,604    27,092           (709)

 

 Farmowners multiple peril         3,093          476     3,064            (56)

 

 Homeowners multiple peril        69,730       11,222    69,036         (1,337)

 

 Commercial multiple peril        35,965        7,021    34,929         (1,790)

 

 Mortgage guaranty                 5,477          912     5,488              2

 

 Ocean marine                      4,837        1,891     4,674           (310)

 

 Inland marine                    14,231        5,540    13,969           (524)

 

 Financial guaranty                5,011        3,218     4,762           (524)

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- occurrence         2,356          229     2,348            (20)

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- claims made        8,964        1,879     8,831           (249)

 

 Earthquake                        2,374        1,073     2,198           (326)

 

 Group accident and health         5,405        1,379     5,210           (343)

 

 Credit accident and health

 

   (group and indiv.)                368          175       368             (1)

 

 Other accident and health         3,503        1,066     3,447           (109)

 

 Workers' compensation            39,338        7,082    38,449         (1,557)

 

 Other liability --

 

   occurrence                     31,228        9,530    29,993         (2,215)

 

 Other liability --

 

   claims made                    20,790        6,365    19,430         (2,345)

 

 Excess workers'

 

   compensation                    1,175          234     1,138            (64)

 

 Products liability --

 

   occurrence                      2,618          624     2,433           (304)

 

 Products liability --

 

   claims made                       503          131       476            (46)

 

 Private passenger auto

 

   liability                     101,827        6,788   101,005         (1,568)

 

 Commercial auto liability        19,987        3,386    19,535           (787)

 

 Auto physical damage             73,313        5,323    72,475         (1,504)

 

 Aircraft (all perils)             2,683        1,459     2,567           (235)

 

 Fidelity                          1,280          181     1,255            (44)

 

 Surety                            5,968        1,092     5,783           (316)

 

 Burglary and theft                  185          32        178            (11)

 

 Boiler and machinery              2,633          829     2,584            (94)

 

 Credit                            2,300        1,075     2,197           (200)

 

 International                       228          85        218            (18)

 

 Warranty                          2,752          995     2,714            (77)

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   property                        8,253        2,043     7,805           (758)

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   liability                       7,572        2,251     7,063           (872)

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assm

 

   financial lines                   296          60        272            (37)

 

 Write-ins for other

 

   lines of business               1,643          362    1,603            (72)

 

      Total                      531,053      107,138  519,855        (20,350)

 

      Capital                    521,736      524,791

 

 

                               [table continued]

 

 

                                             Lower Bound

 

 

                                     %             %         %

 

                                  Drop in      Increase   Drop in

 

                                    TPW        in Price  Coverage

 

 

 Fire                              -3.2%         3.2%     -6.1%

 

 Allied lines                      -1.1%         1.1%     -2.2%

 

 Farmowners multiple peril         -0.9%         0.9%     -1.9%

 

 Homeowners multiple peril         -1.0%         1.0%     -2.0%

 

 Commercial multiple peril         -2.9%         2.9%     -5.6%

 

 Mortgage guaranty                  0.2%        -0.2%      0.4%

 

 Ocean marine                      -3.4%         3.4%     -6.5%

 

 Inland marine                     -1.8%         1.8%     -3.6%

 

 Financial guaranty                -5.0%         5.0%     -9.5%

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- occurrence         -0.3%         0.3%     -0.7%

 

 Medical professional

 

   liability -- claims made        -1.5%         1.5%     -2.9%

 

 Earthquake                        -7.4%         7.4%    -13.8%

 

 Group accident and health         -3.6%         3.6%     -7.0%

 

 Credit accident and health

 

   (group and indiv.)               0.0%         0.0%      0.0%

 

 Other accident and health         -1.6%         1.6%     -3.2%

 

 Workers' compensation             -2.3%         2.3%     -4.4%

 

 Other liability --

 

   occurrence                      -4.0%         4.0%     -7.6%

 

 Other liability --

 

   claims made                     -6.5%         6.5%    -12.3%

 

 Excess workers'

 

   compensation                    -3.2%         3.2%     -6.2%

 

 Products liability --

 

   occurrence                      -7.1%         7.1%    -13.2%

 

 Products liability --

 

   claims made                     -5.4%         5.4%    -10.2%

 

 Private passenger auto

 

   liability                       -0.8%         0.8%     -1.6%

 

 Commercial auto liability         -2.3%         2.3%     -4.4%

 

 Auto physical damage              -1.1%         1.1%     -2.3%

 

 Aircraft (all perils)             -4.3%         4.3%     -8.3%

 

 Fidelity                          -2.0%         2.0%     -3.8%

 

 Surety                            -3.1%         3.1%     -6.0%

 

 Burglary and theft                -3.5%         3.5%     -6.7%

 

 Boiler and machinery              -1.9%         1.9%     -3.7%

 

 Credit                            -4.5%         4.5%     -8.6%

 

 International                     -4.2%         4.2%     -8.0%

 

 Warranty                          -1.4%         1.4%     -2.7%

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   property                        -5.4%         5.4%    -10.3%

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed

 

   liability                       -6.7%         6.7%    -12.6%

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assm

 

   financial lines                 -7.8%         7.8%    -14.5%

 

 Write-ins for other

 

   lines of business               -2.5%         2.5%     -4.8%

 

      Total                        -2.1%         2.1%     -4.1%

 

      Capital

 

 

 Note: TPW is the sum of columns (1) to (3) of Table 4

 

Impact on the Price of Insurance (Step Three)

 

In step three of our analysis, we estimate the impact of the proposed tax on the price of insurance. Adopting the standard approach taken in the academic literature, we define "price" as the ratio of premium earned to losses incurred. The intuition is straightforward: the price that a consumer pays for insurance is equivalent to the premium charged per unit of risk, where risk is defined as losses incurred. (Loss incurred, or the amount of risk insured, is the insurance equivalent of "quantity" in classic microeconomics.)

In keeping with a basic tenet of economics, a decline in the supply of insurance will lead to an increase in price. The magnitude of the increase will depend on the sensitivity of prices to changes in the industrywide supply of insurance. Note the supply of insurance is defined as premiums, not the amount of risk insured or losses incurred. To calculate the price effect in the current context, we observe the change in the price of insurance as a function of supply using industrywide NAIC data that includes standalone insurance companies as well as those that belong to insurance groups.

We estimate that the price of insurance would increase by 1 percent for every 1 percent decrease in the industrywide supply of insurance. (In technical terms, the price elasticity of primary insurance is equal to 1.0.) This translates into an overall increase in price of 2.1 percent per unit of insurance, as shown in the second to the last column of Table 6. Based on the amount of insurance written in 2009, U.S. consumers would have to pay an additional $11 billion a year in premiums to obtain the same insurance coverage.

The second to last column of Table 6 shows the percent increase in price by line of business. Note that some lines would experience a price increase far higher than the overall average. For example, we estimate that the price of earthquake insurance would increase by 7.4 percent. Excess-of-loss reinsurance lines would also see a significant increase in price: property (5.4 percent), liability (6.7 percent), and financial (7.8 percent). The product liability coverage lines would see significant price increases as well (7.1 and 5.4 percent, respectively, for occurrence and claims made).

The last column reports the change in insurance coverage for each line of business: given a reduction in premiums and an increase in the price per unit of risk, the insurance coverage must drop by more than the increase in price. For example, the overall reduction of insurance supply of 2.1 percent and a 2.1 percent increase in the price result in an insurance coverage drop by 4.1 percent (= (1 -- 0.021) / (1 + 0.021) -- 1). The drops in non-proportional reinsurance lines and the earthquake line are far larger than the overall average drop.

 

Modified Analysis

 

In our base-case analysis, we assumed that U.S. subsidiaries would eliminate that portion of their offshore affiliate reinsurance that was deemed "excess" ($26.0 billion) and retain the rest ($3.8 billion). Among other things, we calculated the amount of non-affiliate reinsurance that U.S. subsidiaries would substitute in response to the elimination of that quantity of affiliate reinsurance. However, that very substitution process would render some of the retained offshore affiliate reinsurance "excess." That is so because U.S. subsidiaries already cede a large amount of premium to non-affiliate reinsurers. Thus, given the peculiar way the legislation is written, a further increase in U.S. subsidiaries' use of non-affiliate reinsurance would push some of their "non-excess" offshore affiliate reinsurance above the premium limitation threshold.32 Recall Firm 1 in Figure 7 above.

Stated differently, U.S. subsidiaries would be constrained in their response to the imposition of the proposed tax. Our base-case analysis ignored this constraint, giving us a lower-bound estimate of the impact of the proposed tax. To give us an upper-bound estimate of the impact of the tax, we assume the worst case -- namely, that U.S. subsidiaries would be forced to eliminate all of their offshore affiliate reinsurance as "excess."33

Table 7 reports these upper-bound results. We estimate that, if U.S. subsidiaries were forced to eliminate all of their offshore affiliate reinsurance, the total supply of reinsurance would drop by $23.5 billion, or more than 20 percent. The supply of primary insurance would in turn go down by 2.4 percent. We know from our earlier analysis that a decrease in the supply of insurance leads to an equivalent increase in price. Thus, we estimate that the price of P&C insurance would increase by 2.4 percent, or $13 billion a year on the same insurance coverage.

   Table 7. Impact on U.S. P&C Industry -- Upper Bound ($ in Millions)

 

 

                                    2009                     Upper Bound

 

 

                               Total

 

                               Premium     Total                 Change in

 

                               Written     Reins                 Total Reins

 

                               (TPW)       Ceded        TPW      Ceded

 

 

 Fire                           15,764     5,526     15,149        (1,138)

 

 Allied lines                   27,401    15,604     26,704        (1,487)

 

 Farmowners multiple peril       3,093       476      3,058           (66)

 

 Homeowners multiple peril      69,730    11,222     68,915        (1,552)

 

 Commercial multiple peril      35,965     7,021     34,804        (1,998)

 

 Mortgage guaranty               5,477       912      5,489             2

 

 Ocean marine                    4,837     1,891      4,629          (389)

 

 Inland marine                  14,231     5,540     13,847          (747)

 

 Financial guaranty              5,011     3,218      4,762          (524)

 

 Medical professional            2,356       229      2,348           (22)

 

   liability -- occurrence

 

 Medical professional            8,964     1,879      8,821          (268)

 

   liability -- claims made

 

 Earthquake                      2,374     1,073      2,168          (378)

 

 Group accident and health       5,405     1,379      5,188          (379)

 

 Credit accident and health        368       175        368            (1)

 

   (group and indiv.)

 

 Other accident and health       3,503     1,066      3,446          (112)

 

 Workers' compensation          39,338     7,082     38,417        (1,622)

 

 Other liability --

 

   occurrence                   31,228     9,530     29,879        (2,412)

 

 Other liability -- claims

 

   made                         20,790     6,365     19,265        (2,612)

 

 Excess workers'

 

   compensation                  1,175       234      1,129           (79)

 

 Products liability --

 

   occurrence                    2,618       624      2,426          (315)

 

 Products liability --

 

   claims made                     503       131        472           (52)

 

 Private passenger auto

 

   liability                   101,827     6,788    100,926        (1,721)

 

 Commercial auto liability      19,987     3,386     19,516          (823)

 

 Auto physical damage           73,313     5,323     72,453        (1,562)

 

 Aircraft (all perils)           2,683     1,459      2,501          (357)

 

 Fidelity                        1,280       181      1,255           (44)

 

 Surety                          5,968     1,092      5,763          (348)

 

 Burglary and theft                185        32        178           (12)

 

 Boiler and machinery            2,633       829      2,561          (134)

 

 Credit                          2,300     1,075      2,156          (273)

 

 International                     228        85        217           (20)

 

 Warranty                        2,752       995      2,711           (83)

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed         8,253     2,043      7,740          (862)

 

   property

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed         7,572     2,251      6,975        (1,011)

 

   liability

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assm              296        60        272           (38)

 

   financial lines

 

 Write-ins for other             1,643       362      1,595           (84)

 

   lines of business

 

      Total                    531,053   107,138    518,103       (23,526)

 

      Capital                  521,736              525,125

 

 

                               [table continued]

 

 

                               %              %              %

 

                               Drop in        Increase       Drop in

 

                               TPW            in Price       Coverage

 

 

 Fire                          -3.9%          3.9%           -7.5%

 

 Allied lines                  -2.5%          2.5%           -5.0%

 

 Farmowners multiple peril     -1.1%          1.1%           -2.2%

 

 Homeowners multiple peril     -1.2%          1.2%           -2.3%

 

 Commercial multiple peril     -3.2%          3.2%           -6.3%

 

 Mortgage guaranty              0.2%         -0.2%            0.5%

 

 Ocean marine                  -4.3%          4.3%           -8.2%

 

 Inland marine                 -2.7%          2.7%           -5.3%

 

 Financial guaranty            -5.0%          5.0%           -9.5%

 

 Medical professional          -0.4%          0.4%           -0.7%

 

   liability -- occurrence

 

 Medical professional          -1.6%          1.6%           -3.1%

 

   liability -- claims made

 

 Earthquake                    -8.7%          8.7%          -16.0%

 

 Group accident and health     -4.0%          4.0%           -7.7%

 

 Credit accident and health     0.0%          0.0%            0.0%

 

   (group and indiv.)

 

 Other accident and health     -1.6%          1.6%           -3.2%

 

 Workers' compensation         -2.3%          2.3%           -4.6%

 

 Other liability --            -4.3%          4.3%           -8.3%

 

   occurrence

 

 Other liability -- claims     -7.3%          7.3%          -13.7%

 

   made

 

 Excess workers'               -3.9%          3.9%           -7.6%

 

   compensation

 

 Products liability --         -7.3%          7.3%          -13.6%

 

   occurrence

 

 Products liability --         -6.1%          6.1%          -11.5%

 

   claims made

 

 Private passenger auto        -0.9%          0.9%           -1.8%

 

   liability

 

 Commercial auto liability     -2.4%          2.4%           -4.6%

 

 Auto physical damage          -1.2%          1.2%           -2.3%

 

 Aircraft (all perils)         -6.8%          6.8%          -12.7%

 

 Fidelity                      -2.0%          2.0%           -3.9%

 

 Surety                        -3.4%          3.4%           -6.6%

 

 Burglary and theft            -3.8%          3.8%           -7.3%

 

 Boiler and machinery          -2.7%          2.7%           -5.3%

 

 Credit                        -6.3%          6.3%          -11.8%

 

 International                 -4.9%          4.9%           -9.3%

 

 Warranty                      -1.5%          1.5%           -2.9%

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed       -6.2%          6.2%          -11.7%

 

   property

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assumed       -7.9%          7.9%          -14.6%

 

   liability

 

 Rein: Non-prop. assm          -8.1%          8.1%          -15.0%

 

   financial lines

 

 Write-ins for other           -2.9%          2.9%           -5.6%

 

   lines of business

 

      Total                    -2.4%          2.4%           -4.8%

 

      Capital

 

 

 Note: TPW is the sum of columns (1) to (3) of Table 4.

 

Summary

 

In sum, under our best-case (i.e., base-case) scenario, in which U.S. subsidiaries retain some of their offshore affiliate reinsurance, the supply of P&C insurance in the United States would drop by 2.1 percent, the price would increase by 2.1 percent, or $11 billion for the same insurance coverage. Under the alternative, worst-case scenario, in which U.S. subsidiaries forego all of their offshore affiliate reinsurance, supply would drop by 2.4 percent and price would increase by the same amount, or $13 billion.

The difference between our two sets of estimates may seem surprisingly modest. The explanation is simple, however. Even under our best-case scenario, the legislation would eliminate almost all (87.2 percent) of the offshore affiliate reinsurance. Thus the elimination of all offshore affiliate reinsurance in our worst-case scenario increases the magnitude of the adverse effects identified in our best-case scenario by a relatively small amount.

V. STATE-LEVEL IMPACT

Our analysis thus far has focused on how a tax on offshore affiliate reinsurance would affect U.S. consumers nationwide. Although this is a necessary first step, since most of the relevant data are available only at the national level, the results obscure the fact that some states and regions are more vulnerable than others. In this section, we estimate the impact of the tax on individual states in two ways. First, we apply the estimated nationwide price increases from Table 6 to state-level data on the value of premiums written to estimate the increase in costs to individual states. We present these results for 13 states and 18 lines of business. Second, recognizing that the nationwide estimates significantly understate the impact of the tax on a few sub-national markets, we modify the three-step approach we used to derive those estimates so as to incorporate a proxy for state-level data on reinsurance. By way of illustration, we use this approach to show how the tax will affect multiple peril property insurance in Florida, Louisiana, and Texas.

Linear Allocation of Nationwide Price Increases

Our first approach is a simple linear allocation of the nationwide price increases that we estimated in section V to individual states, based on the value of premiums written in each state. For example, we know that U.S. insurers wrote $977 million of earthquake insurance in California in 2009. If we apply our estimated nationwide price increase for earthquake insurance (7.4 percent) to that figure, we find that Californians would have to pay an additional $72 million for earthquake insurance for the same coverage as a result of the tax ($977 million x .074 = $72 million).

In Appendix B, we present these results for all 50 states plus District of Columbia, and 18 lines of business. We limit our analysis to those lines of business that would experience a nationwide price increase of 2 percent or higher as a result of the tax (see the second to last column in Table 6). Although the non-proportional reinsurance lines would experience among the highest nationwide price increases, the data on premiums written for those lines is not reported by state. Thus, they are not included in the analysis.

Table 8 below shows the total estimated cost increase for the same insurance coverage as in 2009, by state, for all 18 lines of business combined. The hardest-hit states (California, Florida, New York, Texas, New Jersey, Massachusetts and Louisiana) have large, diverse economies with huge exposure to property and liability losses.

            Table 8. Summary of State-Level Impact:

 

              -- Linear Allocation ($ in Millions)

 

 

                         Direct Premiums  Increase in Cost in

 

                           Written (2009)       Selected Lines

 

 

 Arkansas                         1,015                   43

 

 California                      16,691                  771

 

 Florida                          8,525                  361

 

 Iowa                             1,179                   54

 

 Louisiana                        2,520                  108

 

 Massachusetts                    3,570                  164

 

 Montana                            425                   18

 

 Nevada                           1,042                   45

 

 New Jersey                       5,124                  236

 

 New York                        13,345                  627

 

 North Dakota                       294                   13

 

 South Carolina                   1,455                   62

 

 Texas                           10,445                  461

 

 

 Source: Appendix B.

 

California Earthquake Insurance versus Florida Multiple Peril Property Insurance

 

The linear-allocation approach to calculating state-level effects is straightforward, and the results should be reasonably accurate. This approach assumes, however, that the estimated nationwide price increases, by line of business, are a good proxy for the corresponding state-level price increases. That this assumption does not always hold is shown by the contrast between earthquake insurance in California and multiple peril insurance in Florida.

Our estimated nationwide price increase for earthquake insurance (7.4 percent) appears to be a good proxy for the price increase that Californians would see for that type of insurance. Earthquake insurance covers a narrow set of risks, and those risks are heavily concentrated in California. Moreover, the share of earthquake insurance premiums written in California (about half) corresponds to the share of risk that the state contributes to the national total.

Florida multiple peril property insurance offers a contrast. Homeowners multiple peril (HMP) and commercial multiple peril (CMP) insurance provide protection against losses from a great many sources, ranging from wind and hailstorms to fire, theft and lawsuits.34 Our estimated nationwide price increases for HMP and CMP (1.0 and 2.9 percent, respectively) understate the price increases that these states would see. This is because states like Florida and Louisiana are disproportionately hard hit because of their exposure to hurricanes, and therefore are relying more on reinsurance, especially foreign reinsurers, to insure the extreme risk from hurricanes. Heavy reliance on reinsurance also results from the facts that (1) the alternative (capital) is prohibitively expensive, and (2) hurricane risk can be most effectively diversified on a worldwide basis.

Before modifying the linear allocation approach to the state-level impact, we note that the private insurance and reinsurance markets in Florida, Louisiana and several other states do not have sufficient capacity to meet insurance demand for catastrophe coverage. Consequently, state-sponsored entities like Florida Citizens Property Insurance Corporation, Florida Hurricane Catastrophe Fund ("FHCF"), Louisiana Citizens Property Insurance Corporation, and Texas Windstorm Insurance Association fill an increasingly large gap unmet by private markets. For example, Citizens Property in Florida provides 30 percent of homeowners insurance policies, and FHCF supplies 50% of the market demand for reinsurance.35

 

Modified Three-Step Analysis Using Coastal Exposure

 

Because of this heavy reliance on reinsurance, particularly foreign reinsurance, the proposed tax will have an especially large effect on the price of Florida, Louisiana and Texas multiple peril insurance -- more so than our nationwide estimates suggest.

To estimate the actual effect of the tax on multiple peril insurance in Florida, Louisiana and Texas, we run a modified version of our three-step analysis. Since state-level data on reinsurance is not reported, we obtain value of insured residential and commercial coastal exposure for 18 coastal states in 2007 from AIR Worldwide36 and apportion the national reinsurance ceded in HMP and CMP lines to each coastal state in proportion to the state's residential and commercial exposure (see Table 9). For example, the value of Florida's residential coastal exposure is $1,239 billion in 2007, and its commercial coastal exposure is $1,220 billion. The 18 states' residential and commercial coastal exposures total $3,867 and $5,024 billion. (Each state's percentage contribution to the total is reported in the column next to the dollar exposure.) As these states are more heavily exposed to natural disasters such as hurricanes, we assume that these and only these 18 states will purchase reinsurance in the HMP and CMP lines. As a result, we allocate to Florida 32 percent of the national HMP reinsurance ceded, including "excess" offshore affiliate reinsurance. The state's allocation of national CMP reinsurance ceded is 24.3 percent.37

      Table 9. Value of Insured Coastal Exposure in 2007 ($ in

 

                             Billions)

 

 

                  Residential   Percentage  Commercial  Percentage

 

                      Exposure    of Total    Exposure    of Total

 

 Florida              $1,238.6       32.0%    $1,220.0       24.3%

 

 New York               $660.4       17.1%    $1,718.6       34.2%

 

 Texas                  $388.3       10.0%      $506.8       10.1%

 

 Massachusetts          $373.0        9.6%      $399.8        8.0%

 

 New Jersey             $319.5        8.3%      $316.0        6.3%

 

 Connecticut            $250.8        6.5%      $229.1        4.6%

 

 Louisiana               $96.9        2.5%      $127.5        2.5%

 

 S. Carolina             $90.1        2.3%      $101.8        2.0%

 

 Maine                   $81.1        2.1%       $65.9        1.3%

 

 N. Carolina             $78.4        2.0%       $54.4        1.1%

 

 Virginia                $72.6        1.9%       $86.2        1.7%

 

 Alabama                 $46.5        1.2%       $46.0        0.9%

 

 Georgia                 $38.1        1.0%       $47.5        0.9%

 

 Delaware                $36.7        0.9%       $23.8        0.5%

 

 Rhode Island            $31.9        0.8%       $22.2        0.4%

 

 New Hampshire           $30.8        0.8%       $24.9        0.5%

 

 Mississippi             $25.7        0.7%       $26.1        0.5%

 

 Maryland                 $7.2        0.2%        $7.7        0.2%

 

     Total            $3,866.6      100.0%    $5,024.3      100.0%

 

 

 Source: AIR Worldwide.

 

 

We modify our three-step analysis in several ways. First, we extend our methodology in Section IV (line-by-line insurance at the national level) to Florida, Louisiana, and Texas multiple peril property insurance. Second, as described above, we use the percentages in Table 9 above to approximate these states' shares of the national totals for offshore affiliate reinsurance and excess premiums. Third, because of the prohibitively high cost of insuring tail risk with capital in these three states, we exclude the possibility of capital substitution in step one of the analysis.38

Based on this analysis, we estimate that the tax would have the following effects in Florida:

  • increase the price of CMP insurance by 12.6 percent, which represents $264 million a year in added costs for the same coverage; and

  • increase the price of HMP insurance by 4.2 percent, or $266 million a year in added costs.

 

We estimate that the tax would have the following effects in Louisiana:
  • increase the price of CMP insurance by 5.5 percent, which represents $28 million a year in added costs for the same coverage; and

  • increase the price of HMP insurance by 1.4 percent, or $21 million a year in added costs.

 

Similarly, the effects in Texas are:
  • increase the price of CMP insurance by 5.2 percent, which represents $112 million a year in added costs for the same coverage; and

  • increase the price of HMP insurance by 1.5 percent, or $84 million a year in added costs.

 

Moreover, these figures probably still underestimate the impact of the proposed tax on Florida, Louisiana and Texas HMP and CMP prices, for at least two reasons. First, since FHCF provides 50 percent of the reinsurance needs, and it depends on bond markets to fund hurricane losses, the credit crunches and prolonged economic downturn had exacerbated the financial conditions of FHCF.39 State-sponsored entities in Louisiana and Texas face similar challenges. Second, much of the reinsurance for catastrophe risks, including hurricanes, is provided in the two lines of business labeled non-proportional reinsurance (liability and property).40 As we showed in section V, these two lines of business would also see significant price increases -- 6.7 percent and 5.4 percent, respectively -- as a result of the proposed tax. Given that non-proportional reinsurance has become a key input to HMP and CMP, those increases will contribute to yet higher prices for multiple peril insurance.

V. CONCLUSION

We analyze how the U.S. insurance industry would respond to the imposition of a large tax on one particular tool for risk management -- the purchase of reinsurance by U.S. subsidiaries from their foreign affiliates. We find that the supply of reinsurance would contract by 20 percent or more because neither of the alternatives to affiliate reinsurance (capital and non-affiliate reinsurance) is an adequate substitute. This severe contraction of reinsurance in turn would harm the market for primary insurance: supply would drop, and prices would rise, by 2.1 -- 2.4 percent, on average, and significantly more in some lines of business. U.S. consumers, overall, would have to pay $11 -- $13 billion more a year for insurance while at the same time total insurance coverage would decline 4 to 5 percent. The burden of reduced supply and higher prices would fall disproportionately on those states most vulnerable to catastrophic losses, such as California, Florida, New York, Louisiana, and Texas.

Although these estimated effects are large, they are if anything conservative. First, our regression analysis relies on industry data from a period (1996 -- 2006) during which capital was abundant. U.S. insurance companies recently suffered large investment losses due to the financial crisis. While the capital has largely been rebuilt, the financial crisis serves as a cautionary tale as to why affiliated reinsurance is so important: Parental reinsurance support, which can be more easily arranged and which will be reliable year after year, is a far more desirable risk management tool when access to capital was substantially restricted. If our analysis were to reflect the most recent financial crisis and the market turmoil, it would show the effects of the proposed tax to be even more severe.

Second, our analysis assumes that foreign-owned insurance groups could freely transfer capital to their U.S. subsidiaries to make up for reinsurance that is lost. Foreign regulators could impede that process, however, partly in retaliation for a change in longstanding U.S. tax policy that they will clearly view as protectionist. If foreign capital could not flow freely to U.S. insurance subsidiaries, the impact of the proposed tax would be even larger than our estimates indicate.

These statistical estimates do not fully capture the harm that a confiscatory tax on offshore affiliate reinsurance would cause, moreover. Insurance companies use a variety of tools to manage risk, and there are tradeoffs between them. There are compelling economic reasons to believe that the current combination of tools represents the optimal way for the U.S. insurance industry to manage risk. If Congress were to limit or close off any one option, it would reduce the ability of the insurance industry to manage its own risk. As a result, the industry would take on less risk and/or charge more to manage it.

Limiting the use of offshore affiliate reinsurance is especially problematic. Affiliate reinsurance is critical to risk management, because it internalizes the costs of moral hazard and adverse selection and allows insurance groups to transfer risk and losses around the globe quickly and easily. Forcing U.S. subsidiaries to rely more heavily on non-affiliate reinsurance and the capital markets would drive them away from the very high risk lines in which they have traditionally specialized. This would severely restrict the supply of insurance to such lines as nonproportional reinsurance, homeowners insurance in catastrophe-prone states, and commercial liability insurance.

Nor would the effects of the proposed tax be limited to the insurance industry. Consider oil, chemical or manufacturing firms that rely on the P&C industry for liability coverage. At a minimum, they will have to pay more for insurance, and they may face restrictions on the coverage they can get (recall that one way the P&C industry responded to the contraction in the supply of reinsurance in our analysis was by writing less primary insurance). These firms will have to assume more risk themselves at a time when their own capital structure is strained, which could lead them to cut back on investment and might even raise the risk of insolvency. This could have a non-trivial effect on the economy.

In sum, the legislative proposal would lead to a degradation of the ability of firms to manage risk, both inside and outside of the P&C industry. The financial burden of catastrophe risk, in particular, would fall more heavily on the United States, including the U.S. government as the insurer of last resort. Moreover the government would have to bear that burden in the context of an economy weakened by the lack of an adequate capacity for risk-management.

Adoption of such legislation would be imprudent under the best of conditions, and current conditions are anything but good. The risks due to natural catastrophes have been growing for 20 years, and that trend is likely to continue because of the development that has occurred in areas prone to earthquakes and floods. Moreover, the ability of the government and private industry to absorb shocks still remains tentative due to an uncertain economic recovery, because of a financial crisis that stems from poor risk management in the banking and mortgage industries. Thus this is an especially poor time to impose a tax that would further jeopardize our economy's capacity to manage risk.

 

FOOTNOTES

 

 

1 The original study, published two months before H.R. 3424 was introduced in July 2009, was based on a proposed legislation that was fundamentally the same as H.R. 3424. While substantially the same as the original study, this revised study updates the previous analysis with more recent data. Any other significant changes in inputs and assumptions from the original study are noted in the report. The authors would like to acknowledge Dorothy Robyn, a former The Brattle Group principal, for her help in writing the original report.

2 Swiss Re, Natural Catastrophes and Man-Made Disasters from http://www.swissre.com/sigma/.

3 For instance, W.R. Berkley Group, one of the strongest advocates of H.R. 3424, makes extensive use of affiliate reinsurance: 17 of the 22 companies in the Berkley group reinsure most of their business with affiliates.

4 Highline database.

5 Raymond James, "Florida Hurricane Catastrophe Fund: Financing Observations and Perspective," presented to Florida Insurance Council, 2009 Summer Insurance Symposium, June 2, 2009.

6 Insurance Information Institute, "The III Insurance Fact Book 2008." Losses are expressed in 2006 dollars.

7 Robert P. Hartwig and Claire Wilkinson, "Residual Market Property Plans: From Markets of Last Resort to Markets of First Choice," Insurance Information Institute, September 2009 at p. 12.

8 See, e.g., Swiss Re, "Commercial liability: a challenge for businesses and their insurers," Sigma No. 5/2009 at pp. 23 - 24.

9 Note that the reinsurer pays out more than it receives in this example. This is not unusual, especially in recent years.

10 J. David Cummins, Georges Dionne, Robert Gagné and Abdelhakim Nouira, 2008, "The Costs and Benefits of Reinsurance." Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1142954.

11 J. David Cummins, 2007, "Reinsurance for Natural and Man-Made Catastrophes in the United States: Current State of the Market and Regulatory Reforms." Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=997928.

12 J. David Cummins, "The Bermuda Insurance Market: An Economic Analysis," 2008. Available at: http://www.bermuda-insurance.org/pdf-downloads/CumminsReport08.pdf.

13 See, for example, Figure 6.1 in J. David Cummins, "The Bermuda Insurance Market," op. cit.

14 Donald Kramer, "Statement of the Association of Bermuda Insurers and Reinsurers," Hearing before the Senate Finance Committee, September 26, 2007. Available at: http://finance.senate.gov/sitepages/hearing092607.htm.

15 Raymond James, op cit. As will be discussed further in Section V below, Florida's property catastrophe risk insurance relies heavily on state-sponsored reinsurance through Florida Hurricane Catastrophe Fund.

16 U.S. members of Congress have recognized some of the problems with the existing state regulation system in the Dodd-Frank Bill (H.R. 4173, the comprehensive U.S. financial services reform bill), where the U.S. Treasury will gain power to pre-empt state law that is inconsistent with international solvency regulation agreements which Treasury can negotiate with foreign governments.

17 See, for example, Lawrence S. Powell, and David W. Sommer, "Internal Versus External Capital Markets in the Insurance Industry: The Role of Reinsurance," Journal of Financial Service Review, 2007, Vol. 31, pp. 173-188; and Lawrence S. Powell, David W. Sommer, and David L. Eckles, "The Role of Internal Capital Markets in Financial Intermediaries: Evidence from Insurer Groups," The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2008, Vol. 75, No. 2, pp. 439-461.

18 One of the central questions in economics has been why and when firms opt to vertically integrate -- i.e., to acquire goods and services internally versus through an external market exchange. Most theories of vertical integration turn on the presence of some type of market imperfection. Traditional theories emphasized issues of market power (e.g., a firm may seek to capture monopoly profits earned downstream by gaining control of a distribution channel). Over time, however, economists have focused increasingly on the critical role of transaction costs. One branch of work in this area, led by Oliver Williamson (the 2009 Nobel Prize laureate in economics), has looked at conditions under which giving decision making authority to management in a combined firm (vertical integration) is more efficient than contracting out. Another branch of work, for which economists Joseph Stiglitz and George Akerlof won the Nobel Prize, emphasizes that information asymmetries lead to costly moral hazard and adverse selection problems, and that firms integrate vertically to internalize and control these costs. The differences between these branches of work are less important than the similarities, however -- namely, a view that the governance structure that an individual firm voluntarily adopts tends to be the most efficient one possible, given the nature of its transactions.

19 Under existing U.S. tax treaties, reinsurers based in a number of other countries such as Germany and Switzerland pay no federal excise tax.

20 The legislation exempts cessions from U.S. insurers to offshore non-affiliate reinsurers. It also exempts cessions to offshore affiliates that are subject to U.S. income taxation.

21 This calculation assumes a 30 percent ceding commission. Although ceding commissions vary, 30 percent is representative. If anything, the average ceding commission may be slightly lower than 30 percent, in which case the legislative proposal would represent an even higher gross tax on premium ceded offshore.

22 Highline database.

23 Technically speaking, H.R. 3424 stipulates that the industry fraction to be used for any given year would be calculated on the industry data during the second proceeding calendar year.

24 Our original report used NAIC 2007 data, which included only 34 separate lines of business.

25 Although the overall average (12.5 percent in Table 4 below) is close to the overall fraction in Table 3 of the original report (12.0 percent), there are some notable differences in certain lines. For example, the fraction for "Financial guarantee" dropped from 18 percent from the original report to 0.6 percent currently.

26 H.R. 3424 at p. 9 defines the threshold for a foreign-owned company at 25 percent. Our original analysis in 2009 used a higher 50 percent threshold.

27 In keeping with the way NAIC collects and compiles industry data, we treat as insurance the three lines of business labeled "non-proportional reinsurance."

28 U.S.-owned insurers account for about 80 percent of this sample, and U.S. subsidiaries of foreign-owned groups account for the rest. Although we are interested in the behavior of U.S. subsidiaries at this step of the analysis, we include data on U.S.-owned insurers as well. In doing so, we assume that domestic and foreign insurers make financing decisions in a similar manner. Our results validate this assumption. When we eliminate U.S. subsidiaries from our sample, there is no change in the substitution coefficient of non-affiliate reinsurance for affiliate reinsurance and only a small drop in the substitution coefficient of capital for affiliate reinsurance. More generally, our results are not particularly sensitive to variations in the statistical specification and/or the data sample.

29 In technical terms, the substitution coefficient of non- affiliate reinsurance for affiliate reinsurance is 0.29 and the substitution coefficient of capital for affiliate reinsurance is 0.56. These results are consistent with the academic literature as well as our discussions with industry officials.

30 Note that the substitution of non-affiliate reinsurance for "excess" affiliate reinsurance would in many cases have the effect of making additional affiliate reinsurance "excess." Although we ignore that effect here, we take it into account below, in our modified analysis.

31 For certain lines of business, such as homeowners multiple peril, the seeming lack of a significant impact is misleading, for reasons we discuss in section VI on state-level effects.

32 For almost all lines of business, the substitution of non-affiliate reinsurance would displace 100 percent of the offshore affiliate reinsurance. That is so because, under H.R. 3424, close to 90 percent of the offshore affiliate reinsurance for these lines would be deemed "excess" to start with (see Table 5 above). The exceptions include those lines (e.g., allied lines and aircraft (all perils)) for which less than 70 percent of the offshore affiliate reinsurance would initially be deemed "excess."

33 As a technical matter, we incorporate that assumption by modifying the inputs to step one of our three-step analysis. In other respects, the analysis is the same.

34 In addition to commercial businesses, CMP covers losses to commercial properties including condominiums.

35 Raymond James, op cit., at p. 4.

36 See Hartwig and Wilkonson, op cit., Figures 12 and 13.

37 In our previous study, we obtained data from Risk Management Solutions (RMS), a nationally recognized authority on catastrophe risk-modeling, on Florida's contribution to the total risk that the United States faces from the kind of HMP and CMP losses that occur only once every 100 or 250 years (almost all such risk, known as "tail risk," is reinsured). As a comparison, we allocated 56 percent of nationwide HMP and 37 percent of nationwide CMP to Florida. We switch to the current approximation to reflect not just the risk distribution given an extreme tail risk, but also the frequency of less extreme events. The exposures measure both the loss distribution given a loss and also the probabilities of losses.

38 Published commentary and anecdotal evidence suggest that the insurance companies that provide catastrophic insurance in Florida are thinly capitalized and rely primarily on reinsurance to insure hurricane risk. See, for example, Dowling & Partners, IBNR Weekly, January 9, 2009, p. 19. More generally, insurers in catastrophe-prone states appear to rely largely on reinsurance (private reinsurers and state-sponsored funds) to insure tail risks, because the alternative (capital) is so expensive. See also Hartwig and Wilkinson, op cit.

39 Hartwig and Wilkinson, op cit.

40 We understand that, although NAIC requests that companies report non-proportional reinsurance for HMP and CMP under "Reinsurance: Non-Proportional Assumed Liability," some companies report it under "Reinsurance: Non-Proportional Assumed Property."

 

END OF FOOTNOTES

 

 

APPENDIX A

 

 

REGRESSION ANALYSIS AND SIMULATION

 

 

This appendix provides more details of the regression analyses and the simulation of U.S. P&C insurance market under the proposed legislation. The regression analyses consist of three separate regressions.1 First, we estimate the degree of substitutability of non-affiliated reinsurance and capital (surplus) for affiliated reinsurance. In the second regression, we investigate the sensitivity of insurance premium written to ceded reinsurance and surplus. The last regression assesses the impact of a change in industry-wide growth of premiums written on the price of insurance, defined as the ratio of premium earned over the losses incurred. Finally, this appendix describes a simulation of the U.S. P&C insurance market under the proposed legislation. Each of these steps is described in greater detail below.

REGRESSION ANALYSIS #1: SUBSTITUTION FOR AFFILIATED REINSURANCE

Insurance companies manage their business through three main tools -- surplus, affiliated reinsurance, and non-affiliated reinsurance. They are jointly determined. In the regression framework, this results in a system of simultaneous equations where surplus, affiliated, and nonaffiliated reinsurance should all be treated as endogenous variables. Because the tax proposals would directly impact the affiliated reinsurance, we estimate the responses from the other two variables. More specifically, the two regressions are:

 

 

 

 

 

where the variables are defined as in Table A1.2

 

Table A1: Description of the Variables in Regression Analysis

 

#1

 

 

Variable

Variation Dimensions

Description

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

RCTNA

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Reinsurance ceded to non-affiliates divided by total premium written, where the latter measure is defined as direct premium written plus reinsurance assumed from non-affiliates.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

NetRCTA

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Reinsurance ceded to affiliates (net of reinsurance assumed from affiliates) divided by total premium written.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Surplus

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Surplus (i.e., total assets net of total liabilities) divided by total premium written.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Age CatExposure

Variation Dimensions

Across companies Across companies and time

Description

Age of the company as of 2008. Direct premium written by the insurer in property insurance lines in coastal states and earthquake coverage in California divided by total direct premium written.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

HERFGEO

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Herfindahl index of geographic concentration based on direct premium written in each state by the insurer.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

HERFLOB

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Herfindahl index of line of business concentration based on direct premium written in line of business by the insurer.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Assets CoC

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time Across time

Description

Total assets of the insurer. Cost of capital assuming the beta of 1, defined as the market risk premium plus the 3-month Treasury bill rate.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Mutual

Variation Dimensions

Across companies

Description

A dummy variable equal to 1 if the insurer is a mutual and to 0, otherwise.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Line shares

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Direct premium written in each of the lines of business divided by total direct premium written

___________________________________________________________________

To account for endogeneity of the reinsurance variables and surplus in the above equations, we utilize the instrumental variable (2-stage least squares) method. Under this method, we first regress the two endogeneous variables in each equation on the independent variables listed in Table A1 as well as the natural logarithm of the number of affiliates, and the company-to-group size ratio (defined as the ratio of the insurer's assets to the sum of the group's assets). These additional instruments play a role in explaining the instrumented (endogenous) variables.3 In the second step, we run the above equations using the fitted values for the endogenous variables from the first step.

The first regression is in many ways similar to the one performed in Powell and Sommer (2005)4 and Mayers and Smith (1990).5 As affiliated and non-affiliated reinsurance are not perfect substitutes, the expected coefficient on NetRCTA variable is between zero and negative one. The other variables are included in the regression to control for other factors affecting the dependent variable:6

  • The age variable, a proxy for informational asymmetries inherent in reinsurance transactions among non-affiliated entities, is expected to have a positive sign: as insurers get more informed about one another over time, older insurers should be able to find nonaffiliated reinsurance more easily than the newly formed ones.

  • Catastrophe exposure should increase demand for non-affiliated reinsurance because of higher capitalization requirements.7

  • Geographic and line of business concentration could affect demand for reinsurance, although their impact is an empirical matter: On one hand insurers having high geographic or line-of-business concentrations are more susceptible to catastrophic loss. On the other hand, as Powell and Sommer (2005) argue, insurers concentrating in fewer lines or geographic areas may choose less risky lines or choose less risky clients inside their chosen lines.

  • Company size, measured by the natural logarithm of total assets, is a proxy for financial strength of an insurer. Thus larger companies may have fewer incentives to shift part of their risk via reinsurance transactions than smaller companies exposed to greater risk of insolvency.

  • Organizational form of the insurance company may also play a role as found in Mayers and Smith (1990). For example, the agency problems may be less alarming for mutual insurers because their policyholders are also the equity holders of the company. The expected sign is positive.

  • Following Mayers and Smith (1990) and Powell and Sommer (2005), we include the percentage share variables for each line of business, which are proxies for different risks in terms of expected magnitude, cash flow uncertainty and timing.8 These differences across the lines may potentially impact insurer's demand for reinsurance.

  • Finally, we expect a negative relationship between surplus and non-affiliated reinsurance since higher surplus implies higher cushion against unexpected future losses and, all else equal, creates less incentives for seeking reinsurance.

 

As for the second equation, both types of reinsurance are expected to have a negative coefficient estimates. Line variables are important as companies having different business mix may have different capitalization requirements. Coefficient estimate on company size is likely to be negative as larger companies are likely to be both financially stronger and better diversified and will therefore require less surplus per unit of premiums written. We include age to account for possible impact of the years the company has been in business on its surplus. The expected sign on the cost of capital variable is negative as its higher value makes it costly to hold an extra dollar of surplus per unit of premiums written.

Following the academic literature, we delete observations with abnormal values such as negative assets, ceded or assumed reinsurance, and direct premiums written. We also remove observations surplus ratio larger than ten or negative, HERFGEO, HERFLOB, and leverage variables outside the zero to one interval, as well as catastrophic exposure and company-to-group asset ratio variables exceeding one.

We also eliminate all reciprocal and Lloyd's member companies, as well as those which are not part of an affiliated group or which have been created less than two years prior to the observation year. Additionally, we limit our attention to companies that write direct premiums in excess of USD 50 million and those who have reinsurance assumed from non-affiliates not exceeding 75 percent of total premiums written. The former restriction is imposed to capture only the nontrivial participants who are active in the market, while the latter assumption is imposed to eliminate the companies who primarily act as reinsurers.

Table A2 provides a summary of the estimation results.9

                  Table A2: Estimation Results

 

 

                     RCTNA      Surplus

 

 Constant            0.828***   1.536***

 

                     [0.212]    [0.566]

 

 NetRCTA             -0.429*** -1.276***

 

                     [0.034]    [0.134]

 

 RCTNA                         -2.494***

 

                                [0.406]

 

 Surplus            -0.253***

 

                     [0.087]

 

 Ln(Age)             0.021***   0.085***

 

                     [0.008]    [0.013]

 

 CatExposure         0.043

 

                     [0.051]

 

 HERFGEO             0.005

 

                     [0.013]

 

 HERFLOB             -0.018

 

                     [0.021]

 

 Ln(Assets)          -0.031**   -0.044*

 

                     [0.012]    [0.026]

 

 CoC                            0.349

 

                                [0.413]

 

 Mutual              0.016

 

                     [0.013]

 

 

 Observations        7,415      7,415

 

 

 Standard errorsare shown in brackets. Depenedent variables are

 

 RCTNA and Surplus

 

 

 * significant at 10%

 

 

 ** significant at 5%

 

 

 *** significant at 1%

 

 

All of the variables that are statistically significant have the expected signs. As our objective is to quantify the sensitivity of non-affiliated reinsurance and surplus to changes in affiliated reinsurance, we are particularly interested in coefficients on net affiliated reinsurance and surplus in the first equation and coefficients on net affiliated and non-affiliated reinsurance in the second equation. Taking into account that surplus and non-affiliated reinsurance are endogenous in this system, we quantify their sensitivities to a unit shock in affiliated reinsurance ratio as follows:

 

 

 

= (-1.276+(-2.494)x(-0.429))/ (1-(-0.253)x(-2.494)) = - 0.56

 

 

Therefore, all else equal, a unit negative shock to affiliated reinsurance to premiums written ratio will translate into 0.29 units of increment in non-affiliated reinsurance to premiums written ratio and 0.56 units of increment in surplus to premiums written ratio.

REGRESSION ANALYSIS #2: IMPACT OF REINSURANCE AND SURPLUS ON INSURANCE PREMIUM

The analysis in the second regression analysis follows Powell, Sommer, and Eckles (2008).10 Because in the first step of our analysis we have already assessed the impact on surplus and aggregate (i.e., affiliated plus non-affiliated) ceded reinsurance ratios from a unit change in affiliated reinsurance ratio, in the second step we intend to quantify the magnitude of a change in the total premium written by a company per unit change in the aggregate ceded reinsurance. We define our regressions in terms of the growth rates rather than levels. As in the first step of our analysis, we use NAIC data from 1996 through 2006. The following regression is estimated:

 

 

 

where the variables are defined as in Table A3.

Intuition behind this regression specification is straightforward. All else equal, increased reliance on reinsurance should allow an insurance company to write more premiums since by ceding reinsurance it partially protects itself from the risk of unexpected losses. Thus the expected sign on the ceded reinsurance variable is positive in our regression. Instead of relying on reinsurance, an insurance company may increase its surplus, which serves as a cushion against unexpected losses. Keeping everything else constant, increased surplus should enable the company to write more insurance premiums. Thus the growth in surplus represents the company's ability to write more premiums without ceding more reinsurance. Therefore, it is expected that the growth in surplus variable does also have a positive coefficient.

 

Table A3: Description of the Variables

 

 

Variable

Variation Dimensions

Description

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]TPW

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Percentage change in the total premium written.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]RC

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Change in the sum of RCTNA and NetRCTA variables.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]Surplus

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Percentage change in surplus, where surplus is defined as the difference between insurer's assets and liabilities.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]HERFLOB

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Change in the level of the line-of-business concentration.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]HERFGEO

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Change in the level of the geographic concentration.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]CatExposure

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Change in the level of the catastrophe exposure.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]Longtail

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Change in the level of long tail exposure, defined as the ratio of direct premium written in long tail (liability) lines to the total direct premium written by the insurer.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Mutual

Variation Dimensions

Across companies

Description

A dummy variable equal to 1 if the insurer is a mutual and to 0, otherwise.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Year

Variation Dimensions

Across time

Description

Year dummies

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

CompanyCode

Variation Dimensions

Across companies

Description

Company fixed effects / dummies

___________________________________________________________________

While surplus adjustments and ceded reinsurance volumes are important drivers of total premiums written, one needs to control for risk exposure variables as well: even if an insurer keeps the ceded reinsurance ratio and surplus levels constant, decreasing its underwriting exposure via less geographic, line of business concentration or catastrophe exposure should enable it to increase the total premiums written. An insurer's ability to write premiums may also depend on the change in relative magnitude of premiums written in the long-tail lines. On the one hand, higher long-tail exposure may mitigate the pressure on the insurer's capital due to losses being discounted over a longer horizon and therefore allow the insurer to increase total premiums written, all else equal. On the other hand, long-tail lines are associated with higher uncertainty, and increasing long-tail exposure may require additional capital. Depending on which of the two effects dominates, the sign on the long-tail variable can be either negative or positive. Mutual dummy is included to control for the organizational form of the insurer. We also add the year and company dummies to control for fixed effects.

Similar to our regression analysis #1, we drop all the companies whose direct premiums written were less than USD 50 million. To account for possible endogeneity of the growth in ceded reinsurance variable, we utilize the instrumental variable (2-stage least squares) approach by using the all of the remaining independent variables in the regression above as well as the line share variables (see Step 1 regressions). As an additional sensitivity test, we estimate regression where both ceded reinsurance and surplus growth are treated as endogenous variables.

The estimation results are reported in Table A4. In the last column of Table A4, we also report the original estimates from a similar regression in Powell, Sommer, and Eckles (2008) which was estimated using the Generalized Least Squares approach while using the first lag of the growth in surplus variable and treating both change in reinsurance and growth in surplus as exogenous variables.

                  Table A4: Estimation Results

 

 

                      Exogenous Surplus  Endogenous       Powell, Sommer,

 

                                         Surplus           and Eckles (2008)

 

 

 Constant             0.095                0.351           0.072***

 

                      [0.200]            [0.264]           [0.011]

 

 [sum]RC              0.545**            0.677**           0.562***

 

                      [0.246]            [0.272]           [0.029]

 

 [sum]Surplus          0.034*             0.360*           0.137***

 

                      [0.018]            [0.201]           [0.026]

 

 [sum]HERFLOB        0.185***            0.146**           -0.017

 

                      [0.062]            [0.070]           [0.044]

 

 [sum]HERFGEO        -0.139**            -0.131*          -0.534***

 

                      [0.067]            [0.071]           [0.054]

 

 [sum]CatExposure      -0.011             -0.035            -0.046

 

                      [0.062]            [0.067]           [0.051]

 

 [sum]Longtail       0.319***           0.309***           0.199***

 

                      [0.077]            [0.082]           [0.051]

 

 Mutual                -0.078            -0.088*          -0.029***

 

                      [0.049]            [0.052]           [0.011]

 

 

 Observations           4,876              4,876             4,984

 

 

 Standard errors are shown in brackets.

 

 

 Depenedent variable is [sum]TPW

 

 

 * significant at 10%

 

 

 ** significant at 5%

 

 

 *** significant at 1%

 

 

Coefficient on the change in reinsurance ratio is positive and significant in all three regressions. So is the coefficient on the percentage change in surplus (at least, at the 10% level of significance). Coefficient on the reinsurance variable is also relatively stable across different specifications, which, however, is not the case with the surplus growth variable.

REGRESSION ANALYSIS #3: PRICING IMPACT OF REDUCTION IN INSURANCE PREMIUM

In the last regression analysis, we look at how insurance pricing paid by the insured changes per one percent change in the industry-wide premiums written. We define the price of insurance charged by an insurer in each year as the ratio of net premium earned by the company in that year over the losses incurred. Both the definition of the price and the nature of our Step 3 analysis bear certain resemblance to Weiss and Chung (2004)11 who analyzed reinsurance prices in non-proportional property and liability lines.

While in the previous two exercises of our empirical analysis we were dealing only with the insurance companies which have affiliates, in this step we include both companies which have affiliates and stand-alone companies not affiliated with any other insurer. The reason is simple -- the prices are determined based on competition among all participants both group-member companies and stand-alone insurers. Additionally, since the main focus of our Step 3 is the pricing impact of a change in growth rate of industry-wide premiums written and this variable varies only across time and not in the cross section, we restrict our attention to the subset of companies that were in existence prior to 1996 and that do not have any missing or incomplete data since 1996.

For the company-specific information we use NAIC data. For industry-wide total premium written we use data from Total US PC Industry Underwriting and Investment Exhibit as reported by Highline Data. Our regression has the following form:

 

 

 

where the variables are defined as in Table A5.

 

Table A5: Description of the Variables

 

 

Variable

Variation Dimensions

Description

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Price

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Price of insurance defined as premium earned divided by the insurer's losses incurred.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Treasury Rate

Variation Dimensions

Across time

Description

Constant maturity 1-year treasury rate obtained from H-15 database of the Federal Reserve.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

[sum]ATPW

Variation Dimensions

Across time

Description

Percentage change in industry-wide total premium written.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

STL

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

The ratio of policyholders surplus over total liabilities of the insurer.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Assets

Variation Dimensions

Across companies and time

Description

Total assets of the insurer.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Foreign

Variation Dimensions

Across companies

Description

A dummy variable equal to 1 if the insurer is owned by a parent domiciled outside the United States and to 0, otherwise.

___________________________________________________________________

Variable

Mutual

Variation Dimensions

Across companies

Description

A dummy variable equal to 1 if the insurer is a mutual and to 0, otherwise.

Variable

CompanyCode

Variation Dimensions

Across companies

Description

Company fixed effects / dummies

___________________________________________________________________

The intuition behind the choice of the variables is as follows. First, we expect that reduction in the growth of total premiums written will lead to higher prices charged by the companies. Thus our expectation is that the sign on the industry-wide premium growth variable is negative. Lagged price variable is included to capture the time dependency of prices throughout underwriting cycle. Further, according to the "risky debt hypothesis,"12 the buyers of insurance are concerned with the financial quality of the insurance companies. Therefore more financially sound firms command higher prices. Surplus-to-liability ratio and the size of the company, measured by the natural logarithm of total assets, are included as proxies of the financial strength. The expected sign is positive for both variables. Additionally, we include dummy variables for organizational structure (Mutual), ownership domicile (Foreign), as well as company fixed effects.

The regression results are reported in Table A6. As can be seen from Table A6, 1 percent decline in industry-wide premium written growth will lead to nearly 1 percent increment in the prices for insurance. As a robustness check, we also re-estimated our regression using panel fixed effects estimator and found the results to be nearly identical, with the coefficient on ?ATPW equal to -1.057 and statistically significant at the 1% level. Estimation using the lagged 1-year Treasury rate produces a coefficient that is slightly smaller (in absolute value) but is still statistically significant at the 1% level.13 Statistical significance and positive sign on one of the two financial quality variables (namely, the natural logarithm of total assets) provides support for the risky debt hypothesis.

                  Table A6: Estimation Results

 

 

 Constant                 2.100***

 

                           [0.186]

 

 Ln(Price (lagged))       0.224***

 

                           [0.010]

 

 Treasury Rate           -2.169***

 

                           [0.370]

 

 [sum]ATPW (lagged)      -1.049***

 

                           [0.128]

 

 STL (lagged)              0.000**

 

                           [0.000]

 

 Ln(Assets (lagged))      0.036***

 

                           [0.008]

 

 Foreign                     0.036

 

                           [0.029]

 

 Mutual                     -0.054

 

                           [0.035]

 

 

 Observations               11,061

 

 

 Standard errors are shown in brackets.

 

 

 Depenedent variable is Ln(Price)

 

 

 * significant at 10%

 

 

 ** significant at 5%

 

 

  *** significant at 1%

 

 

SIMULATION ANALYSIS: INTERACTION OF REDUCTION IN INDUSTRY-WIDE PREMIUMS AND CHANGE IN REINSURANCE AND CAPITAL LEVELS

Given the parameters estimated from regression analyses #1 and #2, we conduct a simulation to estimate the impact on the U.S. P&C industry. This simulation is necessary because of the feedback loops (see Figure 6 in the report). As the regression analyses show, each insurance company's offering of insurance policies (premiums), and its risk management in terms of capital and reinsurance depend on a number of factors such as size, cost of capital, geographic and line concentration. After controlling for these factors, we estimate the key regression coefficients to reflect the responses of an average insurance company. They correspond to the industry-wide premiums and capital. Hence, we use the industry-wide statistics to simulate the tax proposal's impact. An additional advantage of this approach is that using the industry aggregates smoothes out the "noise" contained in each individual company's premium and capital levels.

In particular, the following equations are used in the simulation:14

 

 

 

Equation (1a) is the substitution function of non-affiliate reinsurance (RCTNAi) for affiliate reinsurance (RCTAi). The functional form of reinsurance ratios follows from the specification in regression analysis #1. Equation (1b) models how capital responds to changes in reinsurance in aggregates. Note that since premium levels (for both direct insurance and reinsurance) are available for each NAIC line, but capital is only available for each line, the regression coefficient for non-affiliate reinsurance (?1) is applied to each NAIC line, but the coefficient for capital (?2) is applied to all lines combined. In the equations above (34 lines plus capital), all variables denoted with a (-1) suffix are known, and NetRCTAi is also known. We need to solve for RCTNAi, Capital, and TPWi. At this stage, there are a total of 35 equations and 69 unknowns (34 RCTNAi, 1 Capital, and 34 TPWi).

From regression analysis #2, we know how TPWi would react if there are changes in reinsurance ratios and capital growth

 

 

 

Equation (2) adds 34 additional constraints on the unknowns. Thus, equations (1a), (1b), and (2) can now be solved simultaneously to obtain RCTNAi, Capital, and TPWi.

In our simulation exercise, we choose the following parameters:

 

 

 

FOOTNOTES

 

 

1 The first two regressions are built on two papers by Prof. Lawrence Powell (see citations below). He assisted us in updating and adapting his research for our research agenda. Errors are ours, though.

2 Note the affiliate reinsurance is defined as the reinsurance ceded to affiliates less reinsurance assumed from affiliates.

3 For example, affiliated reinsurance may be affected by the company-to-group size ratio. If the company is large relative to the entire group, its affiliates may be unable to assume a large share of the premiums that the company decided to cede. On the other hand, the number of affiliates may be important in explaining the affiliated reinsurance as larger number of affiliates can result in better chances of finding an affiliated insurer ready to assume reinsurance from the company in question. Furthermore, if each of the affiliates is targeting a different line of business or geographic area, then the group companies may distribute their risks internally.

4 Powell, Lawrence and David Sommer, "Internal versus External Capital Markets in the Insurance Industry: The Role of Reinsurance," SSRN, 2005.

5 Mayers, David and Clifford W. Smith, Jr, "On the Corporate Demand for Insurance: Evidence from the Reinsurance Market," Journal of Business, 1990, vol. 63, no. 1, pt 1.

6 Two variables in Powell and Sommer (2005) --- tax-exempt interest income and publicly traded dummy variable --- are not included because they are not statistically significant. We also exclude the industry leverage variable since it was collinear with another exogenous variable.

7 The link between catastrophe exposure and affiliated reinsurance is less clear-cut. Powell and Sommer (2005) provide reasons for why insurers with high catastrophe exposure may have fewer incentives to cede less to their affiliates. One of the explanations is that some subsidiaries are created to pigeonhole catastrophic loss risks so that they do not impact other group members.

8 Note that for the purposes of calculating the "Line shares" variables, 31 proportional lines are regrouped into 24 lines by combining "Medical malpractice -- occurrence" with "Medical malpractice -- claims made", "Other liability -- occurrence" with "Other liability -- claims made", "Products liability -- occurrence" with "Products liability -- claims made", as well as combining the three accident and health lines into one line and the three auto lines into one line. We subsequently drop the line variable for "Commercial multiple peril" to avoid singularity in the regression.

9 The coefficient estimates for 23 line variables and the year dummies are not reported.

10 Powell, Lawrence, David Sommer, and David Eckles, "The Role of Internal Capital Markets in Financial Intermediaries: Evidence from Insurer Groups," The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2008, Vol. 75, No. 2, 439-461.

11 Weiss, Mary A. and Joon-Hai Chung, "U.S. Reinsurance Prices, Financial Quality, and Global Capacity," The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2004, Vol. 71, No. 3, 437-467.

12 Cummins, J. David and Patricia M. Danzon, "Price, Financial Quality, and Capital Flows in Insurance Markets," Journal of Financial Intermediation, 1997, Vol. 6, 3-38.

13 The estimate is equal to -0.92 for the least squares regression and -0.93 with the panel fixed effects estimator.

14 The simulation is performed on industry-wide premiums from Highline Data. Because Highline eliminates inter-company reinsurance, the reinsurance premiums assumed to and ceded from affiliates represent reinsurance between NAIC-reporting entities and non-reporting entities. At the industry level, we choose to define gross premium written and reinsurance ceded to affiliates differently from those for each individual the regression analyses. In particular, we include reinsurance assumed from affiliates (these are from non-NAIC-reporting entities) in total premiums written, and not to net reinsurance assumed from affiliate from reinsurance ceded to affiliates.

 

END OF FOOTNOTES

 

 

APPENDIX B

 

 

STATE-LEVEL INCREASE IN THE COST OF INSURANCE

 

FOR SELECTED LINES OF BUSINESS

 

 

[To view Appendix B, See Doc 2010-15377 .]

 

 

ABOUT THE BRATTLE GROUP

The Brattle Group provides consulting and expert testimony in economics, finance, and regulation to corporations, law firms, and governments around the world. We combine in-depth industry experience, rigorous analyses, and principled techniques to help clients answer complex economic and financial questions in litigation and regulation, develop strategies for changing markets, and make critical business decisions. For more information visit www.brattle.com.

ABOUT THE AUTHORS

Dr. Michael Cragg, a principal of The Brattle Group, started his career as an economics professor at Columbia University where he taught public finance. He has worked at RAND and the Milken Institute, and he was a visiting professor at UCLA's Andersen School of Management. His current research focuses on issues in corporate finance, tax, and financial services. Several of his recent engagements have involved the insurance industry. Dr. Cragg holds a Ph.D. from Stanford University and an M.A. from the University of British Columbia.

P: 617.864.7900

 

E: Michael.Cragg@brattle.com

 

 

Dr. J. David Cummins is the Joseph E. Boettner Professor of Risk Management, Insurance, and Financial Institutions at the Fox School of Business at Temple University and the Harry J. Loman Professor Emeritus of Insurance and Risk Management at The Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania. He also serves as the director of the Advanta Center for Financial Institutions and co-editor of the Journal of Banking and Finance. His current research focuses on insurance economics, financial risk management, productivity and efficiency, and securitization. Dr. Cummins holds a Ph.D. and an M.A. from the University of Pennsylvania.

P: 215.204.8468

 

E: Cummins@temple.edu

 

 

Dr. Bin Zhou, a senior consultant of The Brattle Group, specializes in the application of finance, accounting, and taxation in a variety of consulting and litigation settings. He has served as a consulting expert in several high-profile securities and bankruptcy litigation matters and supported academic experts in various stages of the litigation. His work has focused primarily on the economic analysis of structured finance transactions, financial statement analysis, causation, and damages. Dr. Zhou holds a Ph.D. from Brandeis University and an M.A. from Washington State University.

P: 617.864.7900

 

E: Bin.Zhou@brattle.com
DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
  • Authors
    Cragg, Michael
    Cummins, J. David
    Zhou, Bin
  • Institutional Authors
    Brattle Group Inc.
  • Cross-Reference
    For H.R. 3424, see Doc 2009-18189 or 2009 TNT 154-28 2009 TNT 154-28: Proposed Legislation.
  • Code Sections
  • Subject Area/Tax Topics
  • Jurisdictions
  • Language
    English
  • Tax Analysts Document Number
    Doc 2010-15377
  • Tax Analysts Electronic Citation
    2010 TNT 133-24
  • Magazine Citation
    The Insurance Tax Review, Aug. 1, 2010, p. 423
    39 Ins. Tax Rev. 423 (Aug. 1, 2010)
Copy RID