Menu
Tax Notes logo

Treasury Reports on Response of Wealth Accumulation to Estate Taxation

NOV. 1, 2005

OTA Paper 96

DATED NOV. 1, 2005
DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
Citations: OTA Paper 96
THE BEHAVIORAL RESPONSE OF WEALTH ACCUMULATION TO ESTATE TAXATION: TIME SERIES EVIDENCE

 

THE BEHAVIORAL RESPONSE OF

 

WEALTH ACCUMULATION TO ESTATE TAXATION:

 

TIME SERIES EVIDENCE

 

by

 

David Joulfaian

 

US Department of the Treasury

 

OTA Paper 96

 

 

November 2005

 

 

OTA Papers is an occasional series of reports on the research, models, and datasets developed to inform and improve Treasury's tax policy analysis. The papers are works in progress and subject to revision. Views and opinions expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent official Treasury positions or policy. OTA Papers are distributed in order to document OTA analytic methods and data and invite discussion and suggestions for revision and improvement. Comments are welcome and should be directed to the authors.

 

Office of Tax Analysis

 

US Department of the Treasury

 

1500 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW

 

Washington, DC 20220

 

The paper benefited from comments by Gerald Auten and Robert Carroll for helpful comments. The valuable research assistance of Margaret Rolley is gratefully acknowledged. Comments are welcome to david.joulfaian@do.treas.gov.

 

The Behavioral Response of Wealth Accumulation to Estate Taxation:

 

Time Series Evidence

 

 

Abstract

 

 

This paper explores the behavioral response of taxable bequests to estate taxation. To gauge its effects, the estate tax is converted to an equivalent income tax. This highlights the importance of expected rates of return, and also makes it possible to compare effective tax rates on saving over time. Using data on federal revenues from the estate tax over the past 50 years, and employing the equivalent income tax rate measure, the findings suggest that estate taxes have a dampening effect on the reported size of taxable estates. Estate taxation seems to depress taxable bequests by some 14 percent.

Keywords: Saving, Bequests, Taxes

 

JEL: D19, H31

 

 

I. Introduction

Capital taxes create disincentives for saving. Income taxes, such as those that apply to capital gains, interest, and dividends, create disincentives to save by reducing rates of return. Similarly, estate and inheritance taxes may create similar disincentives for the bequest motivated saver (Fiekowsky, 1966; Poterba, 1997). With its repeal on the agenda, as provided for in The Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA), understanding the effects of the estate tax on wealth accumulation is important.

While the disincentives created by capital taxes are clear, a priori, the theoretical effect of these taxes on donors is ambiguous and depends on the offsetting substitution and income effects. More specifically, it depends on the preferences of the potential saver. In the presence of altruistic bequests, for instance, Caballe (1995) and Laitner (2000) simulate the estate tax to have a depressing effect on the capital stock. Similarly, Gale and Perozek (2001) argue that the effects on saving depend critically on the underlying transfer motives. Ultimately, however, the effect of estate taxation is an empirical question. One is tempted to rely on the findings in the literature on the effects of income taxes.1 But because bequest taxes apply to the stock of terminal wealth, they may not be directly comparable to the income tax that applies to the return to saving or income flows during the life cycle.

The scarcity of data on the size and distribution of wealth spanning different tax regimes, particularly for the wealthiest segment of society, has limited the thorough study of the effects of estate taxation. Holtz-Eakin and Marples (2001), for instance, employ the Health and Retirement Survey panel data (HRS), where the wealthy are under represented, to explore the effect of estate taxes on wealth accumulation. They find estate and inheritance taxes to have a depressing effect on wealth accumulation.

Others resort to administrative data. In the most recent study on the effects of the estate tax on wealth accumulation in the US, Kopczuk and Slemrod (2001), hereafter KS, employ estate tax data for the pre-war period, and augment them with limited data for the post war years.2

In an earlier study, Chapman, Hariharan, and Southwick (1996), hereafter CHS, explore how estate taxes affect post war federal government estate and gift tax revenues. In modeling the effects of estate taxes on wealth accumulation, CHS make creative use of annual time series data on federal estate and gift tax revenues. Lacking individual level data, they regress these annual collections on an imputed contemporaneous measure of the estate tax rate. They report tax rates to have a negative effect on this source of revenues to the government.3 The major limitation of this paper is that the dependent variable is the combined sum of estate and gift taxes, two variables that do not always move in tandem and are governed by different tax regimes. Indeed the spike that CHS report in fiscal year 1977 has little to do with estate taxes; it is explained by the acceleration of gifts in 1976 with gift taxes paid in 1977 (Joulfaian, 2004a).4

KS pursue two strategies in examining the effects of the estate tax on wealth. First, they expand on CHS and employ time series analysis using aggregate wealth reported on estate tax returns for the years 1916 through 1945, and select post war years. Using three measures of the tax rate, the maximum, and those imputed for 40 and 100 times per capita wealth, KS report a negative correlation between the share of top wealth-holders and the estate tax rates. This contemporaneous relationship holds controlling for a number of other influences. A similar sentiment is expressed in Kopczuk and Saez (2004) as they contrast the share of household wealth held by the wealthiest estates with contemporaneous estate tax rates.

In the second strategy, KS resort to pooled cross-sectional analyses that make use of individual estate tax returns. Unlike their time series analysis, the effects of the contemporaneous estate tax rate on the size of reported wealth is weak. However, they find much stronger effects when the tax rate is measured using laws that prevailed at age 45 or ten years before death. The estimates from their preferred specification imply that a tax rate of 50 percent reduces reported wealth by about 10.5 percent.

The cutting edge work of KS in exploring pooled data is quite formidable, particularly when compared to their time series analysis as well as that of CHS. Indeed, it is not clear how to interpret the findings from the time series analysis on the effects of contemporaneous tax rates or the econometric problems of time series estimation in general (Auerbach, 2001). How does the tax regime in effect at death explain wealth accumulated during life? After all, if the focus is on wealth accumulation, the behavioral response and estate planning must have preceded the date of death. Thus, KS's analysis of the pooled data and the effects of lagged tax regimes should be viewed as a significant contribution to the literature.

Comparisons of trends in wealth accumulation over time is quite challenging, in particular as gift taxes did not apply prior to mid 1932.5 The easiest way to avoid estate and inheritance taxes is through tax-free lifetime gifts, unless this is checked by the imposition of gift taxes. It is noteworthy that during the congressional deliberations in 1932 to increase the maximum estate tax rate from 20 to 45 percent, and the introduction of a gift tax regime, one individual is reported to have made about $100 million in gifts; another to have made gifts of about $50 million (Roosevelt, 1938: 312). Considering that the entire yield of the estate tax in 1932 was $400 million, the tax-free inter-vivos transfers of $150 million by these two individuals alone, not to mention likely gifts by scores of others, demonstrate the likely sizeable leakages from the estate tax in the early years of its enactment. These leakages make intertemporal comparisons a challenging undertaking, and may produce biased behavioral estimates when periods with and without gift tax regimes are included in the same sample.

In addition to the gift tax regime, and as noted in Auerbach (2001), relying on pre-war data to aid in gauging the effects of the estate tax can be problematic. Also, and as argued in Clotfelter (1985, pp. 240), given the frequent pre-war changes in tax laws, it is not clear which tax regime is driving behavior. Changes in the definition of residency as well as in the tax base only add to this challenge.6

In this paper I address the effects of estate taxation by examining data on federal government revenues from the estate tax for the fiscal years 1949 through 2001, which correspond to terminal wealth in the years 1948 through 2000. I also develop measures of estate tax equivalent income tax rates to gauge the effects of taxation over time. The equivalent income tax rate is the rate that applies to the annual return on an asset that leaves the size of an heir's inheritance unaffected. For a given estate tax rate, the equivalent income tax rate is low during periods of high rates of return expectations, and vice versa. The reported evidence is suggestive of a stronger estate tax effect when using the equivalent income tax measure, and much weaker when the estate tax rate itself is used.

This paper is organized as follows. Section II provides an overview of trends in estate tax collections by the federal government, and the evolving tax regimes. Section III discusses how estate taxes can be analyzed as an equivalent income tax. It also describes the data sources and explains the construction of variables. Section IV presents empirical evidence on the effects of the estate tax. The findings are sensitive to specification and

II. Background

Federal estate tax revenues grew steadily in the post-war period. As shown in Figure 1 and Table 1, estate tax revenues grew from near a billion in 1948 to $25 billion in 2000. Adjusted for inflation, however, the implied growth rate is less impressive.7 Real tax revenues grew through the early 1970s, and precipitately declined in the following years. It was not until the late 1990s that the real levels of the early 1970s were attained. When stated relative to GDP (Figure 2), or relative to household net worth as in Figure 3, revenues grew over the years but never regained the peak collections of the early 1970s. On average, estate taxes represent one quarter of one percent of GDP, and less than one tenth of one percent of the Flow of Funds household wealth.

Studying the revenue streams depicted in Figures 1-3 is not directly helpful in gauging the effects of taxes on accumulated wealth. In particular, economic growth and the evolving structure of the estate tax make it rather difficult to gauge such effects. While inflation adjusted estate tax revenues grew by 376 percent in this period, for instance, the real gross domestic product grew by some 500 percent and US Household net worth and the S&P index grew even faster.

As for the estate tax structure, major changes in tax regimes took place in 1977, 1982 through 1987, and to a lesser extent in 1998 and beyond.8 The size of exempted estate from estate taxation remained at $60,000 through 1976. The exemption was replaced by a unified tax credit which effectively doubled the exemption in value in 1977, and greatly expanded it between 1982 and 1987 to $600,000. In real terms, however, the exemption fell in value in the early years, expanded from 1977 through 1987, and then fell again as shown in Figure 4. Other things equal, this had the effect of expanding the tax base in the earlier as well as later years.

In this period under study, the maximum estate tax rate was reduced from 77 to 70 percent in 1977. It was further reduced to 55 percent, but leaving much of the schedule for lower brackets intact. The introduction of the unified credit, however, effectively reduced the marginal tax rates in the lowest brackets to zero.

Another significant tax reduction took place in 1982, when spousal transfers became exempt from tax. In 1981 and prior years, the deduction for spousal bequests was limited to 50 percent of the estate (as first introduced by the Revenue Act of 1948). But because spousal transfers may potentially enlarge the estate of the surviving spouse, they do not necessarily escape taxation.9 This, at least in part, may explain the growth in revenues in the late 1980s and 1990s as more and more of the estates of surviving spouses became subject to the estate tax. Table 2, which reports information on the life expectancy of surviving spouses, illustrates the potential for recapture of the expanded marital deduction. And Figure 5 depicts the effective rate for the unlimited marital deduction pre and post ERTA81.10

III. Modeling the effects of estate taxation

Much of the wealth held by the very wealthy becomes subject to the estate tax at death. In many ways, the tax can be viewed as an excise tax on large bequests. This tax, which applies once to accumulated savings, is not directly comparable to the income tax which may apply annually to the return on savings. More specifically, the burden of the estate tax, unlike that of the income tax, may vary with the rate of return and the age of the bequest motivated saver.

To facilitate comparisons, this "excise" tax on bequests can be restated as an equivalent income tax that applies to annual accruals of the income on savings. Assuming the bequest motive is the sole purpose for saving, a wealth holder is indifferent between an estate tax that applies to bequests at death and a lifetime annual equivalent income tax on the return to accumulated wealth that leaves the size of transfers to the heirs unaltered.

Algebraically, with a marginal estate tax rate e, estate tax equivalent income tax rate t, expected rate of return r, and life expectancy or holding period n, we should expect the following to hold for wealth saved today:

 

 

 

That is, an individual may save $1 today and leave (1+r)n(1-e) to his heirs in period n. Under an equivalent income tax regime, the heirs receive [1+r(1- ô)]n. The latter term, i.e., r(1-ô) is commonly used in modeling the effects of income taxes on saving. From this identity, the estate tax equivalent income tax rate becomes:

 

 

 

From equation (2) it follows that, for a given estate tax rate, the equivalent income tax rate declines with life expectancy and the expected rate of return. Alternatively stated, older individuals face a higher equivalent income tax rate. But this rate is lower when higher rates of return are expected.11

Figure 6 illustrates the influence of age and rates of return on the measured equivalent income tax rate. Consider a male individual expecting to face an estate tax rate of 55 percent. For an individual age 21, with a rate of return of 10 percent on assets and life expectancy of 54.6 years, the equivalent income tax rate on annual earnings is 16 percent. This declines to 7 percent when a rate of return of 25 percent is expected. The respective tax rates become 68 and 31 percent, respectively, in the case of a 71 year old male with a life expectancy of 12.5 years.

In order to derive equivalent income tax rates some measure of the rate of return expected over the remaining life expectancy is needed. For simplicity, in any given year, this measure is defined as the maximum of the 10-year moving average rate of return to equity, measured as the growth rate of the S&P index, and that of after-tax bond yield. The latter is proxied by the municipal bond yield.12 Figure 7 plots this expected rate of return.

Identifying the tax regime in effect for estate planning purposes is critical. I start with a 10-year lag, but also consider a number of other lags as well. The taxable estate weighted age for decedents in 1998 was about 81.7 years. Life expectancy, again weighted by the size of taxable estates, but evaluated at ten years before death is 15 years.13 Given that the wealthy experience lower mortality rates than those of the general population (Poterba, 2001),14 as well as the five year differential above, the life expectancy is more likely to be closer to 20 years. Thus, the equivalent income tax rate is derived using n=20 in equation (2), but n=15 is also considered.15

To generate the income tax rates, I first employ the maximum estate tax rate. One drawback of this measure is that it may overstate the expected tax rate faced by the less wealthy. As an alternative, I also employ a predicted estate tax rate measure computed using mean taxable estate values. The latter is derived using a taxable estate of $2.2 million reported by the estates of decedents in 1998. The primary limitation of the latter approach is that it overlooks the reductions in the maximum tax rates that took place over time. And, second, it is difficult to properly identify the representative size of wealth as it is likely to be endogenous to the tax regime in place. Figures 8 and 9 plot the estate tax rates in effect over the period 1948 through 2000, along with the derived measures of the equivalent income tax rates using the rates of return in Figure 7.

IV. Empirical Findings

To gauge the effects of estate taxation, I employ data on federal government estate tax collections for the fiscal years 1949 through 2001. These years correspond to transfers or tax liability in calendar years of 1948 through 2000. First, the stream of revenues is normalized by the estate tax rate, net of the state death tax credit rate, to generate proxies for the taxable estates. The latter is then divided by the Flow of Funds household net worth, represented in the dashed line in Figure 3. Next, I regress this ratio, multiplied by 100, on the estate tax equivalent income tax rate, t, as defined in (2).

For the regressors, I begin with a measure based on the maximum estate tax rate, and employ a number of control variables. The latter include the real size of the exempted estate. Expansions in the exemption amount should reduce the size of the dependent variable. I also control for the amount of spousal bequests accorded a marital deduction, measured as a fraction of the estate. The greater the fraction of the estate allowed as a marital deduction the smaller is our dependent variable. Other variables include the S&P index to control for stock market appreciation. This index also controls for the effects of corporate and personal capital gains taxes in as far as they affect the return to holding corporate equity. Table 3 provides descriptive statistics.

Beginning with column one of Table 4, the estimated coefficient on the tax rate is negative with a value of -0.025 (se=0.004). Evaluated at the sample mean value of the share of wealth, the taxable estate elasticity with respect to the tax rate is -0.18.16 This suggests, with the usual caveats, that in the absence of the estate tax, taxable estates may increase by 18 percent.

Moving to the control variables, the size of the estate exemption, as expected, has a dampening affect on the reported taxable estates and the ensuing estate tax revenue. The estimated coefficient is -0.024 (se=0.006). Similarly, and as expected, the marital deduction has a dampening effect on the taxable estate. The estimated coefficient is -0.04 (se=0.02).

Adding a trend variable, or actually year, has little effect on the above estimates, except for the marital deduction where the coefficient is no longer statistically significant (column 2). Little change is also observed in these estimates when the S&P index is considered (column 3). The estimated coefficient on the index is positive, and, not surprisingly, suggests that estate tax wealth rises when the S&P index appreciates. The estimated coefficient on the tax rate is -0.0192 (0.0085), and implies an elasticity with respect of the tax rate of -0.14.

Alternative lags were considered for the specification in column 3. Only the nine-year lag was statistically significant, with almost identical estimates. Of course, ideally all the lagged tax rates should be included in the right hand side as wealth is accumulated over the life cycle. Unfortunately, the correlation between these rates prevents estimation with such a specification.

In column 4 the equivalent income tax rate is replaced with the 10 year lagged estate tax rate. Unlike the previous estimates, the estimated coefficient is now imprecisely measured, with a value of 0.027 (se=0.041). Even though the income tax rate equivalent measure is derived using the same measure of the estate tax rate, the estimated effects diverge, highlighting the importance of the rates of return as predicted in equation (2).

One possible limitation of the estimates in Table 4 is that the maximum tax rate may not be the margin at which some plan their estates. As such, the tax rates may be measured with error for these individuals. As an alternative, the predicted measure of tax rates is employed. As a reminder, this measure is based on an average taxable estate of $2.2 million in 1998, and is adjusted for inflation to generate measures of marginal tax rates for the entire sample period.

These estimated coefficients, now reported in Table 5, are significantly different from those reported earlier. They all retain the same sign, but increase in significance and size. Beginning with column 1 of Table 5, the estimated coefficient on the tax rate is -0.076 (se=0.021), implying an elasticity of taxable estates with respect to tax rates of -0.33. The estimated elasticity changes little, and becomes -0.27, when year and the S&P index are included. These estimates also change little when nine and eight year lags are considered, but become insignificant when lags under eight years are considered.

Given that US household wealth itself might be endogenous to taxes, the estimated elasticities reported in Tables 4 and 5 may be biased.17 Estate tax decedents may very well be representative of the wealthiest segment of the living population. Thus, as an alternative to the above estimates, columns 3 and 4 in Tables 4 and 5 are re-estimated with the dependent variable defined as the log of real taxable estates. The results are reported in Table 6.

In column 1 of Table 6, the estimated coefficient on the equivalent income tax rate is - 0.14, and almost statistically significant at the 5 percent level. In this constant elasticity specification, the coefficient implies an elasticity of taxable bequests with respect to the tax rate of -0.14, identical to that in column 3 of Table 4. In column 2, the tax rate variable is based on the predicted estate tax rate. The estimated effect of the tax rate is virtually unchanged, and again implies an elasticity ofm-0.14. This, however, is in absolute terms smaller than the -0.27 reported in column 3 of Table 5. Columns 3 and 4 replace the equivalent income tax rate with the estate tax rate directly. Again, and as in column 4 of Tables 4 and 5, the estimated effects of the estate tax rate are not precisely measured.

V. Conclusion

This paper explored the effects of estate taxation on bequests using time series data for the period 1948 through 2000. It derives an income tax equivalent measure of the estate tax rate which allows for the effects of estate taxes to vary with the expected rate of return.

Depending on the specification employed, the estimated elasticity of the taxable estate with respect to the equivalent income tax rate is between -0.14 and - 0.27. In other words, and with the usual caveats, the taxable estate is 14 to 27 percent smaller because of the estate tax.18 However, there is greater support for the finding of an elasticity of -0.14. As with much of the work on the taxable income elasticity, it is not clear whether this measures the effects on saving and wealth accumulation, or reflects tax avoidance (Slemrod, 2001). As one example, minority discounts claimed on estate tax returns filed in 2001 reduce taxable estates by about three percent. In the absence of the estate tax, there will be no longer a need to engage in estate planning and employ strategies designed to reduce the reported value of assets. Nevertheless, and as pointed out by Feldstein (1999), both types of response reflect a welfare cost of estate taxation.

 

References

 

 

Auerbach, Alan (2001). "Comments: The Impact of the Estate Tax on Wealth Accumulation and Avoidance Behavior," in Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation, William G. Gale, James R. Hines Jr., and Joel Slemrod, editors, Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution Press.

Auten, Gerald and Robert Carroll (1999). "The Effect of Income Taxes on Household Behavior," Review of Economics and Statistics, November, 81 (4), 681-693.

Bernheim, B. Douglas, (1999) "Taxation and saving," NBER Working Paper 7061.

Bernheim, Douglas B. (1987). "Does the Estate tax Raise Revenues?" in Tax Policy and the Economy 1, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Carroll, Robert (1998). "Do Taxpayers Really Respond to Changes in Tax Rates? Evidence from the 1993 Act," Office of Tax Analysis Working Paper 78, U.S. Department of Treasury.

Chapman, Kenneth, Govind Hariharan, and Lawrence Southwick Jr. (1996). "Estate Taxes and Asset Accumulation," Family Business Review 9 (Fall), 253-68.

Clotfelter, Charles T. (1985). Federal Tax Policy and Charitable Giving, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Feldstein, Martin S. (1995). "The Effect of Marginal Tax Rates on Taxable Income: A Panel Study of the 1986 Tax Reform Act," Journal of Political Economy, June, 103 (3), 551-572.

Feldstein, Martin S. (1999). "Tax Avoidance and the Deadweight Loss of the Income Tax," Review of Economics and Statistics, November, 4 (81), 674-680.

Fiekowsky, Seymour (1966). "The Effects on Saving of the United States Estate and Gift Tax," in Federal Estate and Gift Taxes, edited by Carl Shoup, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Gale, William G. and Maria G. Perozeh (2001). "Do estate Taxes Reduce Saving?" in Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation, edited by William G. Gale, James R. Hines, and Joel Slemrod, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Gruber, Jon and Emmanuel Saez (2002). "The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Evidence and Implications," Journal of Public Economics, April, 84 (1), 1-32.

Holtz-Eakin, Douglas and Donald Marples (2001). "Distortion Costs of Taxing Wealth Accumulation: Income Versus Estate Taxes," NBER Working Paper No. 8261, April.

Internal Revenue Service, Data Book, various years.

Internal Revenue Service, Annual Report of the Commissioner of the Internal Revenue, various years.

Joulfaian, David (2005). "Choosing between Gifts and Bequests: How Taxes Affect the Timing of Wealth Transfers," forthcoming in Journal of Public Economics, NBER working paper 11025.

Joulfaian, David (2004a). "Gift Taxes and Lifetime Transfers: Time Series Evidence," Journal of Public Economics, 88:9-10, August, 2004, 1917-1929.

Joulfaian, David (2004b). "How Estate Taxes Can be Stated as Income Tax Equivalent Taxes," Office of Tax Analysis, US Department of the Treasury, June, mimeo.

Joulfaian, David (1998). "The Federal Estate and Gift tax: Description, Profile of Taxpayers, and Economic Consequences," OTA Paper no. 80, U.S. Department of the Treasury, December.

Kopczuk, Wojciech (forthcoming). "Tax Bases, Tax Rates and the Elasticity of Reported Income," Journal of Public Economics.

Kopczuk, Wojciech and Emmanuel Saez (2004). "Top Wealth Shares in the United States, 1916-2000: Evidence from Estate Tax Returns," National Tax Journal, lvii:2, Part 2, 445-487.

Kopczuk, Wojciech, and Joel Slemrod (2001). "The Impact of the Estate Tax on Wealth Accumulation and Avoidance Behavior," in Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation, William G. Gale, James R. Hines Jr., and Joel Slemrod, editors, Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution Press.

Poterba, James (2001). "Estate and Gift Taxes and Incentives for Inter Vivos Giving in the US," Journal of Public Economics, 79(1), January, pp. 237-64

Poterba, James (1997). The Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns, NBER working paper 6337, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Roosevelt, Franklin D. (1938). The Public Papers and Addresses, v.5, Random House, New York, 312-14

Slemrod, Joel (2001). "A General Model of the Behavioral Response to Taxation," International Tax and Public Finance, 8(2), 119-28.

 

Figure 1. Federal Estate Tax Revenues ($millions)

 

 

 

 

Figure 2. Estate Tax Revenues as Percent of GDP

 

 

 

 

Figure 3. Estate Tax Revenues as Percent of Household Net Worth

 

 

 

 

Figure 4. Estate Tax exemption

 

 

 

 

Figure 5. Marital Deduction

 

 

 

 

Figure 6. Estate Tax Equivalent Income Tax Rates

 

(by Age and Rate of Return)

 

 

 

 

Figure 7. Rates of Return

 

 

 

 

Figure 8: Maximum Estate and Equivalent Income Tax Rates

 

 

 

 

                                Table 1

 

 

                    Estate Tax Revenues ($millions)

 

 

    Year*   Nominal    Real**    Year*  Nominal    Real**

 

    1948     719.3     2,984     1975   4,784.3    8,893

 

    1949     649.2     2,728     1976   5,551.1    9,756

 

    1950     616.8     2,559     1977   5,145.6    8,491

 

    1951     735.4     2,829     1978   5,236.1    8,031

 

    1952     774.3     2,922     1979   6,172.9    8,503

 

    1953     862.2     3,229     1980   6,571.3    7,975

 

    1954     836.2     3,109     1981   7,883.0    8,672

 

    1955   1,047.6     3,909     1982   5,904.3    6,118

 

    1956   1,240.1     4,559     1983   5,858.3    5,882

 

    1957   1,259.1     4,481     1984   6,145.7    5,915

 

    1958   1,215.8     4,207     1985   6,577.5    6,113

 

    1959   1,418.9     4,876     1986   6,990.0    6,378

 

    1960   1,725.1     5,828     1987   7,167.6    6,309

 

    1961   1,777.0     5,943     1988   7,915.5    6,691

 

    1962   1,951.2     6,461     1989   9,371.8    7,558

 

    1963   2,088.7     6,826     1990   9,903.1    7,577

 

    1964   2,424.8     7,822     1991  10,099.3    7,415

 

    1965   2,619.0     8,314     1992  11,140.5    7,940

 

    1966   2,692.2     8,309     1993  13,136.3    9,091

 

    1967   2,679.3     8,022     1994  12,965.0    8,748

 

    1968   3,097.6     8,901     1995  14,975.0    9,826

 

    1969   3,205.2     8,734     1996  17,136.0   10,922

 

    1970   3,303.4     8,514     1997  20,787.0   12,951

 

    1971   5,072.6    12,525     1998  23,136.0   14,194

 

    1972   4,280.1    10,239     1999  24,926.0   14,962

 

    1973   4,594.2    10,347     2000  24,441.0   14,193

 

    1974   4,235.6     8,591

 

 * Lagged fiscal years, proxy for calendar year liabilities.

 

 

 ** Using CPI 82-84=100.

 

 

 Source: Internal Revenue Service, Annual Report of the Commissioner,

 

 various years, and Data Book, various years.

 

 

                                Table 2

 

 

                 Life Expectancy of Surviving Spouses

 

 

                       Relative              Cumulative Relative

 

 Years*              Frequency                      Frequency

 

    <1                   0.042                          0.042

 

     1                   0.063                          0.105

 

     2                   0.064                          0.169

 

     3                   0.054                          0.223

 

     4                   0.066                          0.289

 

     5                   0.059                          0.348

 

     6                   0.054                          0.402

 

     7                   0.058                          0.459

 

     8                   0.047                          0.506

 

     9                   0.033                          0.539

 

    10                   0.034                          0.573

 

    11                   0.031                          0.604

 

    12                   0.026                          0.630

 

    13                   0.027                          0.656

 

    14                   0.025                          0.681

 

    15                   0.025                          0.706

 

    16                   0.022                          0.729

 

    17                   0.020                          0.748

 

    18                   0.021                          0.770

 

    19                   0.016                          0.785

 

    20                   0.016                          0.802

 

    21                   0.013                          0.815

 

    22                   0.017                          0.832

 

    23                   0.019                          0.851

 

    24                   0.012                          0.863

 

    25                   0.014                          0.877

 

    26                   0.015                          0.892

 

    27                   0.010                          0.903

 

    28                   0.013                          0.916

 

    29                   0.007                          0.923

 

    30                   0.013                          0.936

 

    30+                  0.064                          1.000

 

 

 * Distance between deaths of first and second spouse.

 

 Obtained from estate tax returns of decedents in 1995.

 

 

                                Table 3

 

 

                        Descriptive Statistics

 

 

 Variable                               Mean   Std Dev    Min          Max

 

 Year                                    1974 15.44345    1948        2000

 

 Estate Tax ($mil)                      6,359    6,270     617      24,926

 

 Taxable Estates ($mil)                14,622   16,751   1,011      63,913

 

  Percent of GDP (%)                   0.4836   0.0928  0.3439      0.7379

 

  Percent of Household Net Worth (%)   0.1392   0.0232  0.0994      0.2209

 

 Maximum Estate Tax Rate (%)            68.74    10.08   55.00       77.00

 

 Net Estate Tax Rate (%)                52.74    10.08   39.00       61.00

 

 Equivalent Income Tax Rate (%)         81.66    44.74   28.48      219.84

 

 Exemption Amount                     240,645  240,870  60,000     675,000

 

 Real Exemption                       267,146  114,421 105,448     528,169

 

 Marital Deduction (%)                   59.3     14.2    50.0        97.9

 

 

 S&P Index                                228      316      15       1,427

 

 S&P Moving Average Growth Rate          0.09     0.04    0.00        0.16

 

 Expected Rate of Return (r)             0.09     0.03    0.03        0.16

 

 Real GDP ($Bil)                        4,711    2,316   1,634       9,817

 

 Household Net Worth ($Bil)            10,580   11,553     894      42,332

 

 CPI                                    73.21    50.00   23.80      172.20

 

 

             Tax Variables Computed at Mean Taxable Estate

 

 Taxable Estate ($mil)                 17,269   14,784   2,084     600,795

 

  Percent of GDP (%)                   0.7973   0.2897  0.3917      1.4519

 

  Percent of Household Net Worth (%)   0.2329   0.0897  0.1110      0.4346

 

 Estate Tax Rate (%)                    38.30     6.73   32.00       49.00

 

 Net Estate Tax Rate (%)                33.37     4.84   28.80       41.80

 

 Equivalent Income Tax Rate (%)         31.15    10.61   14.82       59.26

 

 

                                Table 4

 

 

 The Determinants of the Ratio of Taxable Estates to Household Wealth,

 

  1948-2000 (Using maximum estate tax rate; coefficients followed by

 

                    standard errors in parentheses)

 

 

 Variable                         (1)           (2)        (3)        (4)

 

 Intercept                       0.4556*     1.0417*    1.0449*     0.3635

 

                                (0.0682)    (0.4766)   (0.4720)   (0.6762)

 

 In (Estate Tax Rate)t-10                --          --         --     0.0272

 

                                      --          --         --   (0.0409)

 

 In Equivalent Income Tax       -0.0248*    -0.0282*   -0.0192*         --

 

 (Rate)t-10                     (0.0044)    (0.0052)   (0.0085)         --

 

 

 In (Real Exemption)            -0.0235*    -0.0195*   -0.0261*   -0.0332*

 

                                (0.0062)    (0.0069)   (0.0085)   (0.0084)

 

 Marital Deduction %            -0.0398*     -0.0304    -0.0212    -0.0280

 

                                (0.0192)    (0.0205)   (0.0215)   (0.0242)

 

 In Real S&P                          --          --     0.0129    0.0340*

 

                                      --          --   (0.0098)   (0.0082)

 

 Year                                 --     -0.0003    -0.0003     0.0000

 

                                      --    (0.0003)   (0.0003)   (0.0003)

 

 Elasticity                        -0.18       -0.20      -0.14       0.20

 

 Adjusted R2                     0.7136      0.7175     0.7230     0.6883

 

 Observations (regression)            42          42         42         42

 

 

 * Significant at the 5 percent level, ** at the 10 percent level.

 

 

                                Table 5

 

 

   Determinants of the Ratio of Taxable Estates to Household Wealth,

 

    1948-2000 (Using a predicted estate tax rate; coefficients and

 

                    standard errors in parentheses)

 

 

 Variable                        (1)          (2)              (3)        (4)

 

 Intercept                     1.5901*     7.7784*         9.0923*    8.8519*

 

                              (0.2355)    (0.7981)        (0.9089)   (1.8742)

 

 In (Estate Tax Rate)t-10              --          --              --  -0.1083

 

                                    --          --              --   (0.1132)

 

 In Equivalent Income Tax     -0.0765*    -0.0873*        -0.0624*         --

 

 (Rate)t-10                   (0.0206)    (0.0129)        (0.0156)         --

 

 In (Real Exemption)          -0.1090*    -0.0422*        -0.0721*   -0.1035*

 

                              (0.0195)    (0.0148)        (0.0182)   (0.0215)

 

 Marital Deduction %          -0.1617*    -0.1136*         -0.0573    -0.0412

 

                              (0.0595)    (0.0376)        (0.0416)   (0.0493)

 

 In Real S&P                        --          --        (0.0369*    0.0825*

 

                                    --          --        (0.0145)   (0.0163)

 

 Year                               --    -0.0036*        -0.0042*   -0.0040*

 

                                    --    (0.0005)        (0.0005)    (0.0008)

 

 Elasticity                      -0.33       -0.37           -0.27       -0.47

 

 Adjusted R2                     0.8475      0.9463          0.9481      0.9274

 

 Observations (regression)          42          42              42          42

 

 

 * Significant at the 5 percent level, ** at the 10 percent level.

 

 

                                              Table 6

 

 

                   Determinants of the In Real Taxable Estates, 1948-2000

 

                       (Coefficients and standard errors in parentheses)

 

 

 Variable                        (1)         (2)         (3)            (4)

 

 Intercept                    10.2904*   10.0271*    9.8077*        10.3568*

 

                              (1.4998)   (1.4973)   (1.5330)        (1.8043)

 

 In (Estate Tax Rate)t-10           --         --    -0.2136          0.3816

 

                                    --         --     0.5426          0.5601

 

 In Equivalent Income Tax    -0.1377**  -0.1372**         --              --

 

 (Rate)t-10                   (0.0776)   (0.0823)         --              --

 

 In (Real Exemption)          -0.2746*   -0.2714*   -0.2499*        -0.2528*

 

                              (0.1191)   (0.1190)    (0.1232)       (0.1232)

 

 Marital Deduction %          -0.5512*   -0.5638*    -0.4776*       -0.4733*

 

                              (0.2041)   (0.2041)    (0.2075)       (0.2079)

 

 In Real S&P                   0.4279*    0.4434*     0.4411*        0.4338*

 

                              (0.1037)   (0.1042)    (0.1107)       (0.1119)

 

 Elasticity                      -0.14      -0.14       -0.21           0.38

 

 Adjusted R2                    0.9066     0.9064      0.8992         0.8994

 

 DW                             2.1028      2.055      2.0084         2.0088

 

 

 Columns (1) and (2) replicate column (3) in Tables 4 and 5, while (3)

 

 and (4) replicate column (4) in Tables 4 and 5. Estimates corrected for

 

 auto-correlation with AR(1).

 

 

 * Significant at the 5 percent level, ** at the 10 percent level.

 

 

 Number      Authors                  Title                                Date

 

 95      David Joulfaian  Basic Facts on Charitable Giving                06/05

 

 94    Curtis P. Carlson  The Effect of the 2001 Recession and Recent     06/05

 

                          Tax Changes on the Corporate Alternative

 

                          Minimum Tax

 

 93    Curtis P. Carlson  The Corporate Alternative Minimum Tax,          06/05

 

                          Aggregate Historical Trends

 

 92      David Joulfaian  Estate Taxes and Charitable Bequests: Evidence  03/05

 

                          from Two Tax Regimes

 

 91      Warren B. Hrung  Information, the Introduction of Roths, and IRA 12/04

 

                          Participation

 

 90    Janet G. McCubbin  Optimal Tax Enforcement: A Review of the        12/04

 

                          Literature and Practical Implications

 

 89       Scott Jaquette  Recent Trends in Stock Options                  03/03

 

         Matthew Knittel

 

              Karl Russo

 

 88          Peter Brady  Regional Differences in the Utilization of the  08/01

 

       Julie-Anne Cronin  Mortgage Interest Deduction

 

            Scott Houser

 

 87      Robert Rebelein  Who Pays the Individual AMT?                    06/00

 

         Jerry Tempalski

 

 86      David Joulfaian  Choosing Between Gifts and Bequests: How        05/00

 

                          Taxes Affect the Timing of Wealth Transfers

 

 85    Julie-Anne Cronin  U.S. Treasury Distributional Methodology        09/99

 

 84          Laura Power  The Effect of Tax-Based Savings Incentives on   07/99

 

              Mark Rider  the Self-Employed

 

 83         Joann Weiner  Using the Experience in the U.S. States to      04/99

 

                          Evaluate Issues in Implementing Formula

 

                          Apportionment at the International Level

 

 82 Rev.   Nicholas Bull  Defining and Measuring Marriage Penalties and   11/99

 

        Janet Holtzblatt  Bonuses

 

          James R. Nunns

 

         Robert Rebelein

 

 81 Rev. Jerry Tempalski  Revenue Effects of Major Tax Bills              07/03

 

 81      Jerry Tempalski  Revenue Effects of Major Tax Bills              12/98

 

 80      David Joulfaian  The Federal Estate and Gift Tax: Description,   12/98

 

                          Profile of Taxpayers, and Economic

 

                          Consequences

 

 79       Robert Carroll  Do Taxpayers Really Respond to Changes in Tax   11/98

 

                          Rates? Evidence from the 1993 Tax Act

 

FOOTNOTES

 

 

1 For the taxable income response see Feldstein (1995), Auten and Carroll (1999), Carroll (1998), Gruber and Saez (2002), and Kopczuk (forthcoming). For the effects on savings, see Bernheim (1999).

2 Generally reliable cross sectional estate tax data are available for deaths in 1982 and most of later years. Reliable data is also generally available for the years 1962, 1969, 1972, and 1976. For prior years, data is available for the period 1917 through 1945.

3 While the authors report findings on the contemporaneous effects of taxes, their estimates actually reflect a forward looking process as the lead tax rate is employed. Tax collections usually lag the liability year. Much of the collections in fiscal year 1990, for instance, reflect wealth and tax liability in calendar year 1989. Thus their specification generally tests, for example, whether the tax rate in 1990 affected wealth reported in 1989.

4 The maximum gift tax rate increased from 57.75 in 1976 to 70 percent in 1977.

5 The federal government introduced a gift tax in 1924 which was repealed in 1926.

6 The introduction of the US Treasury Liberty Bonds and, subsequently, Flower Bonds which may be viewed as a prepayment, albeit at a discount, of estate taxes (bonds as a form of life insurance), further complicates intertemporal comparisons. Similar complications are introduced by the treatment of pensions and annuities.

7 Again, these actually refer to fiscal years 1949 and 2001. Tax collections usually lag liabilities, reflecting filing requirements. Estate tax collection data is obtained from the IRS Annual Report of the Commissioner (various years) as well as the IRS Data Book (various years).

8 These include the Tax Reform Act of 1976 (TRA76), the Economic Recovery and Tax Act of 1981 (ERTA81), and the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 (TRA97).

9 Throughout this period state Elder Laws, which dictate pre-set amounts or shares of estates to be set aside for the surviving spouse, were also changing further confounding the measurement of the effects of estate taxation.

10 This represents an attempt to control for statutory changes in the allowed marital deduction. Of course there is no guarantee that the surviving spouse won't spend down her wealth. To make post 1981 data comparable to prior years, the marital deduction for this period is set equal to 0.5 + 0.5*(1-m) of the estate, where m is the cumulative probability of death of the surviving spouse.

11 The challenge here is to derive economy wide tax rate to capture differences in life expectancies. Joulfaian (2004b) applies mortality rates to estate tax data to arrive at such a measure. In many ways this is similar to that of Poterba (1997) who applied mortality rates to the living population.

12 Much of the return on equity can be avoided by the step up in basis at death. Replacing municipal bonds with taxable corporate bonds has little effect on the findings.

13 This is computed using the general population life expectancy. See http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr52/nvsr52_14.pdf.

14 For mortality rates of annuitants, which are much lower than those of the general population, see http://library.soa.org:8080/xtbml/tableList.zip.

15 The empirical findings are little affected when n=15 years is employed. Ideally life expectancy should vary by the age of the wealth holder, and using a representative measure of life expectancy may lead to aggregation bias.

16 The elasticity is computed by multiplying the estimated coefficient on the tax rate by the inverse of the wealth share. The mean wealth share, multiplied by 100, is 0.1392 as in table 3.

17 Even those not sufficiently wealthy to be subject to taxation, may be affected by the estate tax. Interestingly, a recent CBS News/New York Times poll found that 71 percent of Americans favored eliminating the tax. http://www.cbsnews.com/stories/2001/03/14/politics/main278884.shtml.

18 Note that some of the reduction in taxable estates may be recaptured under the income tax. Inflated executor commissions paid to a relative, for instance, are taxed under the income tax as compensation. Similarly, undervaluation of estates may lead to greater capital gains realizations by the heirs.

 

END OF FOOTNOTES
DOCUMENT ATTRIBUTES
Copy RID